American economic foreign policy and the origins of the cold war

Authors Avatar

                                                                

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                        

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                

ALTHOUGH THE COLD WAR came to an end more than a decade ago, historians have yet to reach a consensus on the origins of this conflict. Shortly after the proclamation of the Truman doctrine in 1947, which marked the first official announcement of America’s involvement in an antagonistic relationship with the Soviet Union, two major camps with competing explanations on who was to blame for this state-of-affairs emerged. Their views remain among the most hotly debated topics in recent diplomatic history. On the one hand, the orthodox camp maintains that the Cold War was the inevitable response of American policymakers to what were perceived as clear signs of Soviet aggression at the end of the Second World War, especially concerning the formation of a closed communist bloc in Eastern Europe. On the other hand, the revisionist camp contends that Soviet actions were of a purely defensive nature, and, by implication, the creation of a Russian sphere of influence was not the cause of the Cold War, but the result of it. Although many revisionists have divergent views on several important issues, they all draw attention to the role of American economic and ideological factors in the origins of the Cold War. “Leaders of the United States had become convinced, revisionists assert, that survival of the capitalist system at home required the unlimited expansion of American influence overseas.” The argument of this study draws heavily upon the insights of the revisionist camp, but diverges in several important respects. Economic expansionism was not the prime motive behind American foreign policies in the 1940s, but was part of a larger strategy fundamentally aimed at creating economic security, domestically and internationally, in order to prevent the emergence of similar circumstances to the ones that had caused World War II. Although a cautionary stand must be taken in placing any blame for the emergence of the Cold War, the American course of action can at least be seen to have seriously exacerbated tensions between the Soviet Union and the United States.

One important notion where orthodox and revisionist historians appear to concur is that American foreign policy in the 1940s was largely shaped by lessons of the past. By latest after the attack on Pearl Harbor, policymakers in Washington were remarkably unanimous in their belief that that outbreak of the Second World War had been indirectly caused by major errors of the American government during the interwar period. According to Paterson, “Americans studied their own “mistakes” – their rejection of the League of Nations, high tariffs, and restrained involvement in international crises – all of which tugged at the national conscience after 1939.” Furthermore, lenient treatment of the countries that had started World War I was believed to have only resulted in further aggression. As a result, Americans were determined to “get the job right” this time around. President Roosevelt himself promised in a speech given in September 1942: “We have profited by our past mistakes. This time we shall know how to make full use of our victory.” Two important prerequisites to prevent the recurrence of major global wars would be to completely defeat and disarm Germany, and to ensure American membership in a collective security organization that would uphold the international order. Additionally, government leaders in Washington believed that future wars could only be avoided if the United States took an active role in leading the world economy and kept it in a proper functioning order – free from any major depressions. Underlying this view was the classical economists’ assumption that depressions gave rise to wars, whereas free multilateral trade maximized international prosperity and peace. Pollard argues that for American planners in the 1940s, this classical notion was underscored by three important historical experiences: the seemingly effortless workings of the nineteenth-century international economy, the problems of post-World War I finance and trade, and the Great Depression.

        According to Pollard, “The thriving international economy and relatively peaceful political climate from 1815 to 1913 demonstrated the value of free trade, stable and convertible currencies based on gold, and minimal governmental interference (except for London’s role as a financial center).” American political leaders perceived the gold standard, as managed by the Bank of England, as responsible for having stabilized currency exchanges and prices, and for having ensured a steady growth in production and trade among Western industrial countries during that period. Britain was able to manage the international economy and facilitated world liquidity and trade before World War I by eliminating most barriers to foreign imports and by balancing its massive current account surpluses with capital outflows. However, with the outbreak of the First World War, this system came to an abrupt end: economic functions of governments in the West expanded, the gold standard became unsettled, traditional patterns of trade broke, and Europe’s role in world trade and finance started to decline. The Peace of Versailles failed to address major economic issues, and Britain lacked the financial resources to reassume its pre-War role and revive the monetary system. In fact, the one nation capable of taking on economic leadership – the United States – was not willing to do so, largely due to Congressional opposition to the cancellation of allied war debts and the reduction of trade barriers. Accordingly, responsibility for international lending had to be left in private hands. For this reason, Kindleberger argues that America must share a large part of the blame for the ensuing world depression. American protectionism and recurrent trade surpluses during the 1920s had prevented European countries from paying off their war debts through trade, and the U.S. failure to regulate private loans to Europe encouraged highly speculative and irresponsible investment. Moreover, the Federal Reserve’s tightening of the money supply during the early 1930s precipitated the financial crisis in Europe, while several notorious tariffs of 1930 triggered a wave of worldwide protectionism. As prices fell and unemployment spread, the major industrial countries hastened to protect their native industries by raising barriers to foreign goods and devaluating their currencies. From 1929 to 1932, world prices plummeted forty-seven percent, the value of world trade by sixty percent, and employment in industrial countries by twenty-five million.

Join now!

“The impact of the prewar world depression and the experience of the 1930s profoundly colored United States planning of its postwar peace aims.” American policymakers in the forties regarded reconstruction of the world’s economy as an essential goal if the conditions which caused wars were to be eliminated. As argued by Gaddis, “To them, the coincidence of world depression with the rise of dictators seemed more than accidental – almost unanimously they accepted the argument that economic distress led to war.” Hitler, Mussolini, and the Japanese militarists had not appeared out of nowhere; without favorable environments their movements would have never succeeded. ...

This is a preview of the whole essay