To what extent was independence a gift from Britain.

Authors Avatar

          To what extent was independence a gift from Britain

        On 14 of August 1947, Prime Minister Nehru spoke of the handover of power being ‘a moment… in history, when we step out from the old to the new’.  This message, coming from one crucial in the independence movement, unsurprisingly carries connotations of Independence coming through the actions of Indians, with a sense of growth alien to British interests and control.  In contrast to the violent upsurge against the French in Indo-China, the reasons behind the annexation of India from the British Empire are both subtle and complex. While in a violent uprising it is relatively simple to discern that power has been taken, rather than given, the non-cooperation tactics employed in India clarifies little.  The steady rise in pressure from Indian nationalists in conjunction with the apparently hurried withdrawal in 1947 have lead to a belief that Britain was effectively forced out of India.  Whilst a possibility, this must however be regarded in relation to Britain’s changing objectives in an alien world to that of the early ideology of the Raj.

        In terms of historiography, two divergent views can clearly be discerned.  That of the neo-imperialist presents independence as a nurtured gift of British benevolence.  Exponents of this theory such as Sir Percival Griffiths point out that, ‘other ruling powers have abdicated after defeat in war or as a result of successful insurrection, but it was left for Britain to surrender her authority… as part of a process of devolution which had been operating for some time.’  While as a superficial judgement this statement proves true, for Britain did never lose complete control, it does perhaps insinuate a control in withdrawal that is inconsistent with the hurried exit of 1947.  The concept of a state abdicating control of an advantageous situation by its own volition makes little sense, nor is there any precedent for this policy before the First World War.  Statements of Lord Hardinge in 1912 boldly spoke of the ‘permanence of British rule in India’ and so the neo-Imperial stipulation of plans for ‘devolution, which had been in operation for some time’ cannot wholly be upheld, indeed it was not until 1942 that any affirmative time scale was introduced, or so claims the Nationalist interpretation. Here the Cripps offer of 1942 is seen as a ‘post dated cheque’ by the Indian scholar Sumit Sarkar, and independence is presented as seized from Imperial Britain by virtue of irresistible pressure by congress and its allies.  This too however must also be seen to be draw from only a partial reading of events.  As Griffiths points out, British control, though strained and tested, was not broken.  Power was not seized, but granted by an act of the imperial parliament at Westminster.  As such these polarized interpretations can be seen to reflect only half-truths, simplistic interpretations of a long and complex road to Indian freedom.  In broad terms certain factors must be established and accepted, such as the vital and necessary role of a nationalist movement calling for independence.  The claim that states do not willingly give up occupation must be considered in relation to possible economic motives, with the role of resistance within states leading to economic loss also taken into account.  Due to statements such as that of Lord Hardinge’s in 1912, it must be conceded that Britain initially desired to continue the Raj before the First World War, however this cannot not be accepted ‘de facto’ there onwards.

        One possible explanation for Britain’s withdrawal in 1947, which suggests independence was given willingly, is the diminishing importance of India and South East Asia.  Both politically and economically Britain was, by 1947, deeply evolved in the Middle East.  The oil-rich nature of many of these nations contrasted sharply with lack of Indian productivity for, as Lord Wavell specified, ‘India will never, within any time we can foresee, be an efficient country’.  This sentiment from the Viceroy in 1944 could be dismissed as simply seeking to save face except that it is from a private document to Prime Minister Churchill, and so can be seen as a reliable insight into the direction of British thought.  The later mention of India possibly becoming ‘a running sore which will sap the strength of the British Empire’ further suggests the lack of any economic basis for Britain holding onto India.  One of the primary reasons for this was that the prosperity and efficiency of the Raj rested with an Indian populace that, even by 1941, was only 7% literate.  Not only is this figure inconsistent with the British desire for efficiency, when coupled with a lack of self sufficiency (on average between 1930-40 once every four years around three million tons of grain had to be imported to avert famine, 4.27 million in 1936) this clearly illustrates part of India’s economic weakness.  Nevertheless, the fact that literacy was rising and these problems were not new, clearly indicates that economic inefficiency did not give immediate rise to any British need to quit India.  Instead, the role of trade, particularly in the rapidly changing post war situation, is far more significant.  Crucially it is here that major profit is made, and Britain’s dominance was in decline.  

Join now!

In contrast to Britain’s pre-war profits from cotton trade imports to India of £37.9 million, the rise in imports from Japan and America (by some 400% overall) can be linked with the decline in cotton trade profits to £27.2 million in 1919, a shift that Lawrence James terms as a ‘fracture’ to the Anglo-Indian economic inter-dependency.  This is perhaps the most accurate reflection but of greater interest is the £100 million of British War debt that the Indian Government assimilated in return for being able to tax Lancashire cottons.  This ability to obtain concessions from the British Government due to its financial ...

This is a preview of the whole essay