September, 2004                                        

         

                               India’s Growth Prospects: Revisited

                                                     

        A couple of years ago I published a paper in EPW on India’s medium-term growth prospects (Acharya:2002b) in which I concluded that “On a balance of considerations, it might be reasonable to expect growth in the next five years to fluctuate in the range of 4 to 6 percent, perhaps averaging close to 5 percent.” A few months later the Tenth Five Year Plan was published, boldly projecting 8 percent growth for the period, 2002/3-2006/7, despite the anemic performance of 4 percent expansion in the first year, 2002/3, of the Plan. The drumbeat of growth optimism continued in ensuing months fuelled by the strong economic recovery of 2003/4 and a spate of analytical papers (including in EPW) extolling India’s medium and long-term growth prospects. The drumroll reached a crescendo in the early spring of 2004 with the “India Shining” campaign. While the totally unexpected election results of May, 2004 have taken much of the shine off the shining campaign, the academic optimists still march boldly on (for example, Kelkar:2004 and Rodrik and Subramanian:2004).

        In the light of such growth optimism of the past two years should I revise the  more moderate medium-term growth outlook presented in my earlier paper? That is the issue I address in this brief paper.

I. Short-term Factors

        As noted above, short-term euphoria about India’s growth prospects rose to a peak in early 2004 fuelled by the CSO’s advance estimate of 8 percent plus GDP growth in 2003/4. The third quarter (Oct.-Dec., 2003) estimate of 10.4 percent GDP growth induced headlines of India being the fastest growing economy in the world. Senior government spokesmen (including then finance minister, Jaswant Singh) confidently projected 8 percent growth in the medium-term. Election pamphlets were even more bullish and foresaw growth in double digits!

To begin with, let’s put the 8.1 percent growth of 2003/4 in perspective. As  Table 1 shows, it follows a sluggish 4 percent rate recorded in 2002/3, coming after a Ninth Plan (1997-2002) average growth of 5.5 percent, which, in turn, reflected a marked slowdown from the reform-driven growth surge of 6.7 percent experienced in 1992-97. Much of the economic dynamism of 2003/4 simply reflects an exceptional rebound in agriculture from a drought-affected 5 percent drop in 2002/3 to a strong 9 percent recovery thanks to the best monsoon in over twenty years. Services also grew strongly and industry did moderately well. If the last two years are averaged, then agriculture reverts to the recent trend of 2 percent growth and overall GDP shows a healthy but unremarkable 6 percent increase. Quite clearly, there is no compelling evidence here supporting medium-term growth expectations of 8 percent aspired to in the Tenth Plan.

Table 1:Growth of GDP and Major Sectors

(average annual growth, percent per annum)

a : Quick Estimates; b : Advance Estimates

Sources: CSO; Economic Survey 2003/4.

II. Longer-term Factors

        In any case, the short-term euphoria of spring 2004 was effectively punctured by the unexpected election results of May and the wayward monsoon of 2004. Most non-official growth forecasts for 2004/5 (as available in September 2004) cluster around a modest 5.5 to 6 percent. However, the growth optimism of recent years also draws strength from a set of analytical papers that have appeared over the past year propounding the case for rapid (7 percent plus), long-run growth of the Indian economy. In this review I shall focus on three main contributions: the much talked about “BRICs report” by Goldman Sachs of October 2003 ( Wilson and Purushothaman: 2003), Vijay Kelkar’s April 2004 Narayanan oration at the Australian National University (Kelkar: 2004) and Rodrik and Subramanian (2004) in EPW (henceforth referred as RS). While these papers vary substantially in their scope and emphasis, they share a very bullish outlook on India’s medium and long-run growth prospects.

The main factors on which such growth optimism is based are: India’s demographic outlook for the next 40 years, past and projected trends in productivity, the country’s institutional strengths and underlying optimism about reforms. Let us consider each of these factors.

Demographic Dividend: Labour

        All three studies rely heavily on the demographic dividend arising from India’s relatively young population, coupled with declining fertility, which will ensure a rapidly growing labour force and a declining dependency ratio. Rodrik-Subramanium foresee the dependency ratio falling from 0.62 in 2000 to 0.48 in 2025, while working age population continues to grow at nearly 2 percent per year for the next 20 years.  The BRICs study waxes eloquent: “Demographics play an important role in the way the world will change…With the only population out of the BRICs that continues to grow throughout the next 50 years, India has the potential to raise its US dollar income per capita to 35 times current levels” by 2050.

        Note one absolutely crucial point. The demographic dividend is all about the supply of labour. Nothing is said about demand. There in lies the catch. The additional labour supply offers the potential for employment and growth. In a well-functioning economy with competitive product and factor markets labour demand would match supply and lead to more jobs and output. But there is no guarantee of such a happy outcome. It all depends on how well the economy is run; in particular, how well labour markets work. Let’s return to the reality of India. Between 1993/94 and 1999/2000 the economy grew at over 6.5 percent per year. But, according to the Tenth Plan, employment grew hardly 1 percent per annum. This was a period when labour force was growing at over 2 percent a year and there was plenty of backlog of under-employment and unemployment. Quite clearly, labour demand was growing far slower than labour supply. The labour market was far from perfect. There were many reasons. An important one is our rigid labour laws, which effectively convert labour from a variable to a fixed factor of production. Employers in the organized sector have every reason to avoid hiring new workers knowing it is almost impossible to lay off workers in a downturn. (In sharp contrast, firms in China employ millions of new workers each year knowing that they can be laid off if business conditions worsen. Of course, with capital surging in to avail of cheap, productive labour the downturn never comes!)

        Another crucial point is that India’s demographic trajectory is an average of the demographic paths of its constituent states. From around 1970, the fertility story has diverged considerably across states. For various reasons (including female education, gender parity, and improving incomes) Kerala led the way with rapid decline in fertility, followed by Tamil Nadu and other southern states and, subsequently, other states. By 1995, fertility rates (average live births per woman) in Kerala and Tamil Nadu had dropped below replacement level (2.1), other southern states and Maharashta had fertility levels below 3, another group of states had fertility levels between 3 and 4, while the BIMARU states (undivided) and Haryana still had rates above 4.  In a recent EPW paper Leela and Pravin Visaria (2003) have presented long-term population projections for these three groups of states. These are shown in the Table 2 along with data on recent per capita incomes and state GSDP growth. What do the data show?

Join now!

        First, the four BIMARU states had low per capita incomes (averaging below Rs. 10,000 per year) in 1999/2000 compared to the five low-fertility leaders in the demographic transition which averaged over Rs. 18000. Second, the BIMARU economies had grown at an average rate of only 4.6 percent over the decade 1992-2002 compared to the 6.3 percent clocked by the low-fertility states. The disparity is greater in terms of per capita income growth since population in BIMARU states has grown faster. Third, precisely because the BIMARU states are laggards in the demographic transition, they will see the highest relative and ...

This is a preview of the whole essay