Shakeouts in Digital Markets: LESSONS FROM B2B EXCHANGES ContentsLessons from History The Boom-and-Bust in B2B Exchanges The Boom in Exchanges The Bust in Exchanges Triggering the Bust Understanding Digital Markets The Digital Market Continuum Customer Behavior Leveragability of Incumbent Advantages Ability to Capture Value from Internet Technologies Constraints and Inhibitors First Mover Advantages Acceptance of Non-Traditional Pricing Structures Strategies for Winners Adaptive Survivors Acquisitive Incumbents Pure-Play Winners Strategies for Also-Rans Summary: What Have We Learned? APPENDIX A Tracking Exits by B2B Exchanges  Sample selection Notes Shakeouts loom large in the landscape of all fast-growing markets. During the boom period, an unsustainable glut of competitors is attracted by forecasts of high growth and promises of exceptional returns. Even when the market is already crowded, more entrants keep arriving. These followers are often naïve about the barriers to entry and don't realize how many others are also poised to enter at the same time. Reality intrudes with a bust that precipitates the exit of more than 80 percent of the players through failure or acquisition. This shakeout is triggered by some combination of disappointing growth, pricing pressures that degrade profit prospects, or shortages of crucial people and financial resources.(n1)Only the strongest and most resilient firms can survive a shakeout. This is a pattern that was played out as long ago as the genesis of the railroad, telephone, and automobile industries and as recently as software and personal computers. Consider that fifteen years ago there were 832 PC makers; now there are arguably eight to ten viable survivors. That history is now being repeated in virtually every Internet-enabled market.By the end of 2000, collapsing equity prices and catchy headlines such as "The Dot-coms Are Falling to Earth" and "Is That E-Commerce Roadkill I See?" confirmed the onset of a bust in digital markets.(n2) Since the shakeout has happened at an unprecedented pace, the question is whether it was like those in the past or did it create new rules.The abruptness of this shakeout offers new insights into the boom and bust process. The short and unhappy history of business-to-business exchanges is representative of the long-run transformative possibilities of the Internet that attracted a glut of competitors and the collective delusion that led to widespread exits.Lessons from History The first lesson is that pure-play dot-coms will survive and prosper only in breakthrough markets. These online markets are the handful of applications that could not have been realized without the Internet. A corollary is that established firms will have the upper hand in markets that have been re-formed by the Internet. In re-formed applications, network technologies help to squeeze out costs and facilitate interactions, but don't change the basic structure and functioning of the market.In retrospect the vast majority of applications of the Internet were to re-form markets, so it follows that the prospects for most pure-play start-ups were delusional in the past and bleak in the future. The vast majority of start-ups are in the process of exiting their markets; but in contrast with past shakeouts where most exits were by merger, we expect a much higher proportion will simply close their doors.A further lesson is that both the pure plays that survive and the incumbents that gain an advantage from this disruptive innovation will have all the attributes of adaptive survivors of precursor shakeouts.(n3) The companies that remain standing will be a resilient synthesis of old and new.The Boom-and-Bust in B2B Exchanges Shakeouts in the old economy took years to unfold. In the relatively fast-paced market for hard-disk drives for PCs, ten years passed between the entry of the first firm in 1979 and the onset of the shakeout. In the new economy hothouse, thousands of Internet players were spawned between 1998 and 2000. Truly there was a glut of entrants when at least 150 online brokerages, 1000 travel-related sites, 40 online commercial printers, and 30 health and beauty sites were vying for attention and advantage.The Boom in Exchanges Few e-commerce arenas have been more contested than online Business-to-Business (B2B) exchanges;(n4) 280 were visible at the end of 1999, and, a year later, a peak of 1520 was reached (see Exhibit 1).(n5) Most entrants were pure plays such as MetalSite, Chemdex, and Neoforma, attracted by the opportunity to help buyers and sellers efficiently connect with each other in large markets. These exchanges offered various combinations of six core services: information exchange; digital catalogs that help to automate the procurement process; auctions that attract large numbers of suppliers to compete for contracts; logistics services to facilitate the physical movement of goods; collaborative planning so different members of a supply chain can view each others' inventory levels and production schedules; and value-added services such as design collaboration, financing, or offline brokering.The possibility that these independent virtual marketplaces, with no ties to any specific buyers or sellers, might control trade across an industry soon energized the incumbents. Some responded by launching their own sites to streamline the purchasing process. Many also joined their rivals in consortia such as Enerva in chemicals, e2open in electronics, and Transora, a consumer products marketplace with over 50 companies including Kraft, Procter & Gamble, and Unilever. The biggest was Covisint, which managed more than $33 Billion in transactions for Ford, GM, and DaimlerChrysler in the first six months of 2001. These consortia and private networks were only a small proportion of the total; the independents were 92 percent of the total number of exchanges in early 2001.The Bust in Exchanges By late spring 2000 there was a glut of independent exchanges. An estimated 140 start-ups had crowded into the industrial supplies industry, 110 were identified in the food and beverage industry and 55 in construction markets. They were attracted by the revolutionary potential of the Internet. Their fuel was free-flowing capital that was less interested in demonstrating long-run profitability than in creating a compelling story so the venture capitalists and owners could cash out. There were few barriers to entry. By contrast with most emerging markets that are hobbled in their early stages by standards disputes or competition for the best or dominant design, the adoption of universal open standards for exchanging information on the Internet put these constraints to the side.(n6) A market can absorb a diversity of firms if each pursues a distinct and sheltered niche with a hard to match business model. Two features of the Internet pushed new entrants to converge on the same place. The fixation on reaching the scale needed to cover ostensibly fixed costs meant everyone started in the biggest zone of the market, and then edged out into as many related segments as they could handle. This was aided and abetted by the ease with which new features by direct rivals could be copied.The rush for the exit did not begin until early 2001 when the start-ups began running out of cash. According to our longitudinal study of eight industries, only 43% of the independent exchanges survived to July 2002 (see Appendix for the details of our methodology). Exchanges that were linked to an incumbent had a 51% survival rate, but many of these were apparently absorbed by the incumbent. This survival rate is undoubtedly too high as we only tracked exchanges that had received at least one round of funding. These criteria excluded many nascent start-ups that put up sites with a URL but could not get established.The resulting trajectory of exits in Exhibit 1 is consistent with forecasts that there will only be 180 exchanges by the middle 2003.(n7) If so, the boom and bust cycle will span a mere five years, clocking a pace that is five to ten times as fast as in the old economy. The average length of the shakeout period was over ten years during the first half of the 20th century. Typical shakeouts began 20 to 30 years after the first company entered the new market.(n8) The main mode of exit for the independent exchanges was through acquisition by another exchange. This accounted for 31% of the firms, while another 26% ceased operations. There was high variance among industries with the electronics component industry having a high survival rate of 67%, largely because they focused more on complementary services such as the provision of hard-to-find items and the liquidation of excess inventories. The grocery industry had the lowest survival rate with only 24% of the independent exchanges continuing to operate. Most of these exchanges focused on hosting transactions between growers and importers of perishables and grocery wholesalers, who in turn sold to independent retailers or to the distribution arms of retailers like Kroger and Supervalue. Although the opportunity was tempting, the existing processes proved to be faster and simpler,(n9) so the exchange provided little value.Triggering the Bust The overt trigger of the implosion of independent exchanges was a cash crisis brought on by continuing losses and an abrupt withdrawal of venture capital. What caused the investors to lose faith?The first reason was the recognition that many exchanges would not achieve a critical mass of vendors and buyers.(n10) Too many potential participants were skeptical. Suppliers were especially worried that the ease of price comparisons would increase margin pressure by focusing buying decisions on price. Furthermore the technology seldom lived up to the promises. Front-end interfaces were hard to navigate, while back-end transaction processing and administrative systems could not be connected to legacy systems. Both vendors and buyers worried about viruses and security breaches that could compromise confidential information.Prospects for independent exchanges were further dimmed by a shift toward large industry-wide exchanges run by consortia of incumbent companies. Their advantages are a guaranteed source of transaction volume, financial strength, and an ability to develop standards that facilitate interoperability. These consortia seem to work best when there are a small number of founders. When there are many participants, such as Transora with 49 founders, the risk is that no one participant has a strong commitment to the survival of the exchange.(n11) However, even the consortia model may be supplanted by private networks that overcome the governance problems. Thus both GM and the U.S. arm of DaimlerChrysler are developing their own private B2B systems even as they participate in Covisint.(n12) Thus one plausible scenario is that each industry will eventually have one or two public exchanges to simply help buyers and sellers find each other. Subsequent transactions would take place on private networks where logistic arrangements could be optimized and proprietary information safely exchanged. A few specialized exchanges would be available to
Join now!
conduct auctions or offer specialized services such as financing or moving excess inventory. In short, the supply chain will be more efficient but the market landscape would look much as it did before the boom in independent exchanges. This is a scenario that is applicable to the large majority of e-commerce applications.The overshooting of the eventual carrying capacity of most e-commerce markets and the rapid rush for the exit were aggravated by widespread delusions that the Internet would rewrite the old rules of competition and create breakthrough applications in every market. In retrospect, there were only a handful of these ...

This is a preview of the whole essay