The most prominent mode of transferring control of corporate assets is merger. Recall that a merger is a transaction in which one corporation (the acquired) secures title to the stock or assets of another (the acquired).

Authors Avatar

                                             INTRODUCTION

The most prominent mode of transferring control of corporate assets is merger. Recall that a merger is a transaction in which one corporation (the acquired) secures title to the stock or assets of another (the acquired). Consummation of a merger requires the approves the transaction, it puts the merger proposal to a stockholder vote. Depending on the percentage of favourable votes required by the state corporate code, the merger is approved or rejected. In effect, though, management has a veto power over all merger proposals and can refuse to put any proposal to a stockholder vote. Tender offers, by contract, do not require the explicit approval of the incumbent management. A tender offer is a public offer made by the management of one firm (the bidder) to purchase a block of another (the target) firm’s outstanding common stock. Tender offers are made directly to the target’s stockholders. If enough stockholders tender, control of the corporation changes hands. Unlike mergers or tender offers, where control passes to those who can convince stockholders to trade their shares, in proxy contents most stockholders do not transfer ownership of their shares. Their incentive is simply to elect the management team that will enhance the value of their investment.  

In the first part of my assignment I will write about corporate control. Also I will write about effect on shareholder value through Micheal Porter view. I will focus my work on mergers and de-mergers and how managers and investors manage their own portfolios of shares.

Corporate Control

From even the most casual reference to the popular financial press, it is clear there is an active market where the control of public corporation is traded. Headlines regularly announce proposals of corporate mergers and acquisitions. Tender offers have become a widespread, much publicized means of changing control and the size of the targets is becoming ever larger. Along with these fairly recent developments, the old-fashioned proxy fight now appears to be undergoing a dramatic revival. Once a phenomenon associated almost exclusively with small companies, proxy challenges have just succeeded in outgoing directors of companies as large as Superior Oil and GAF. All these events, together with the less frequent, though increasingly common news of divestitures, spin-offs and leveraged buyouts are signs of the vigorous working of a market for corporate control.

The existence of a well-functioning market for transferring corporate control has important economic implications. To many disinterested viewers, and no doubt to most incumbent managements whose jobs are threatened by such developments, the wave of mergers, acquisitions and tender offers may seem to reflect the spectacle of managerial empire building in which stockholder’s interests are routinely sacrificed in a general management design to enlarge its own corporate domain. And boards of directors doubtless view proxy fights as an unwelcome and unjustifiable nuisance, interfering with their efforts to run the company. But although the scepticism about acquiring managements and dissident stockholders may be justified in some and perhaps many cases, the market for corporate control provide the mechanism by which corporate assets can be channelled to those most efficient in using them. And this, as most economists would agree is essential to the functioning of the economy as a whole.

The threat of takeover is also a crucial means of disciplining inept management and of curbing the inevitable self-interest of those corporate managers who would prefer to pursue more private goals at their stockholder’s expense. In this sense, the existence of an active market for corporate control is perhaps the best replay to the popular corporate criticism declaiming against the “separation of ownership and control”. Such a market provides ideally, at least, if not always in practice a self-regulating, monitoring mechanism which ensures that management’s interests cannot diverge too far from those of stockholders. In so doing, an efficient market for changing corporate control increases the wealth of all stockholders.

Such a market also contributes to the general economic welfare by providing the opportunity for firms to combine to form more efficient and profitable entities. Whether through economies of scale, improved access to capital markets, combination of complementary resources, or any of the value creating strategies that come under the term “synergies”, mergers and acquisitions hold out the possibility of gains to stockholders of both acquired and acquiring firms. Critics of “big business” continue, of course, to view mergers and acquisitions as a net drain on the economy, wasting capital that could be channelled into more productive investment. However, academic studies have demonstrated conclusively that such transactions even after the expense of engaging the apparently non-productive services of lawyers, accountants and investment bankers – significantly increase the net wealth of stockholders.

Join now!

A more controversial issue, both on Wall Street and academic finance circles alike, concerns the pricing, and thus the profitability of corporate acquisitions to buying companies. The dramatic increase in acquisitions purchase premiums over the past few years has raised questions about both the efficiency of the market in pricing stocks and the motives of managements of acquiring companies. If stock prices have not significantly understated the value of corporate assets, it is difficult to imagine how DuPont’s recent acquisitions of Conoco at a price that represents a premium of over 100 percent above Conoco’s pre-offer price – can turn ...

This is a preview of the whole essay