Why Was The Bank Of England Permitted To Decide Interest Rates?

Authors Avatar

Simon Ball                Bank Of England Independence

Whither Independence -

Why Was The Bank Of England Permitted To Decide Interest Rates?

The first substantive economic policy implemented by New Labour after the 1997 election was the decision to grant the Bank of England operational independence. In an unexpected move that shocked journalists, analysts and commentators alike, the Treasury ceded responsibility for interest rate policy to the bank, subject to an externally imposed inflation target. Though the economic justification for granting the bank independence was entirely sound, in retrospect, the government’s political motives were equally as important. Regardless of the motivation, six years later, the decision to grant the Bank of England is regarded by many, as New Labour’s most successful and expedient economic policy.

The decision to grant the Bank of England operational independence was regarded as “an astonishingly bold start for a new chancellor”. However, the idea of an independent central bank is by no means new. Many leading industrial economies had independent central banks years before Britain. In the case of some nations, most notably Germany, the independence of the central bank and its success in controlling inflation is credited as a major factor of economic success. The argument that the Bank of England should be independent had been gaining strength with economic commentators since the late 1980’s, especially in the wake of the high inflation experienced during the Lawson boom. The economic case for central bank independence is fairly clear. In order to control inflation, it is necessary to reduce the inflation expectation of wage and price setters. Therefore, the credibility of a central bank’s commitment to combating inflation is critical. If a central bank has a poor record in fighting inflation, wage and price setters are likely to distrust its forecasts, and thus will consider overestimating inflation as less risky than underestimating it. The result is a high expectation, and thus, high inflation. To reduce the inflation expectation today, price and wage setters have to be confident that future inflation will be low. The best way to induce this confidence is for the central bank to commit itself to achieving low inflation, and to be seen to be adhering to this target. A central bank that is seen to be hell-bent on achieving low inflation, gives wage and price setters the confidence to constrain their inflation expectations. Therefore, a central bank can achieve low inflation only if its commitment to inflation is credible.

Unfortunately, the credibility of a central bank’s commitment to low inflation is very easily undermined if monetary policy is subject to the influence from short-term political considerations that override prudent economics. Governments are subject to three basic temptations when considering monetary policy: -

  • The first temptation is that, facing spending requirements that outstrip tax revenues, a politically weak government can finance the fiscal deficit by borrowing. However, since debt interest ultimately has to be repaid, either through higher taxation or lower spending, it may become very tempting for a government facing a high burden to dilute the real value of its debt through inflation.

  • The second temptation is that even if a government does not intend to inflate away its nominal debt, it can seek to reduce the cost of servicing its debt by pushing down interest rates. Of course, falling interest rates inevitably lead to inflation eventually.

  • The final temptation a government can face is the desire to use monetary policy to support its political fortunes. Using monetary policy to generate an inflationary boom just before a general election is a common political trick, but it unfortunately tends to erode the credibility of the government’s commitment to low inflation in subsequent years. If wage-setters hedge against later inflation by increasing their inflation expectation in the early years of a government, it can make subsequent disinflation very difficult.

Even if a government manages to resist these specific temptations, the basic problem remains – controlling inflation in the long-term may require actions that have negative political consequences in the short-term. Interest rates have to be changed months before they will have any visible effect on inflation. However, as long as an increase in the rate of interest results in higher mortgage repayments for the electorate, governments will tend to delay any increase until it is too late, and cut rates before it is prudent to do so. Consequently, when inflation does become visible, it is much higher than would be the case if action had been taken early. The cumulative effect of these temptations to ignore monetary prudence in favour of political expediency is to all but destroy the credibility of a central bank’s commitment to low inflation. This of course makes reducing inflation expectations virtually impossible.

Join now!

Given the tendency for politicians to give undue weight to short-term political considerations, a strong case emerges for precommitting to a low inflation policy by removing monetary policy from immediate government control – hence the saying “The only good central bank is one that can say no to politicians”. Only an independent central bank under the control of professional bankers and free from political influence can credibly pre-commit to the objective of achieving low inflation. If the bank can be seen to be adhering to this objective in the face of pressure to change its course, it gains credibility ...

This is a preview of the whole essay