Outline the background to China's One Child Family policy and assess its likely success.

Authors Avatar

0233311

Outline the background to China’s One Child Family policy and assess its likely success.

China has long been a nation with a large populace.  By the time the People’s Republic of China (PRC) was founded in 1949 its population totalled 540 million.  By July 1990 China’s population reached 1.16 billion and accounted for 22% of the world’s population (Chen, 1995).  In addition to a rapid increase in population, poor population characteristics and uneven distribution have affected the country’s development.  Few countries in the world cope with such high population pressures as China’s thus social and economic problems are inevitable consequences.  In response to such pressures China’s family planning program, particularly its 1979 mandatory one child policy, has received a large amount of the attention from the world’s academic community.  This is partly because of the relatively limited access to information that China provided, but is also a product of widespread acknowledgment of the measurable, though not universal, success of its various birth-control programs.  These programs have tended to be tied to economic and political shifts within the country.  Elisabeth Croll divides these shifts into three family models beginning in 1949.  The Complex Peasant Family Model was in effect from 1949 to 1969 and was concerned mainly with ideological shifts from the traditional “ideal” Chinese family to the family unit as a part of the communist regime.  The Small Family Model was practical from 1970 to 1978 and centred on voluntary birth reduction for urban families and lenient birth limits for peasant families (Croll, 1985).  The Single-Child Family Model has dominated Chinese policy since 1979 (Winckler 2002).  China’s one child family policy has remained in place despite the widespread political and social change that has been implemented over the past two decades.  It emerged from the belief that rapid unbridled population growth, and its resulting increase in numbers of young people, could seriously threaten the future development of the country.  Each of these models has produced reaction from the Chinese people and changes in population; I will outline the reasons for the reactions, the predictions about the consequences of continuing the policy and the possible advisability of the policy more generally.  Integral to this is the success of the one child policy in terms of public response to policy implementation, along with its demographic consequences, both intended and unintended.  Scholarly consensus is that while the one-child policy has, to some extent, succeeded in stemming China’s population growth; it has also spawned inequitable social outcomes; elements of which can be isolated as having significant implications for China’s future.  

Notwithstanding significant uncertainties with regard to demographic events in China, its population problem has subsisted throughout hundreds of years of history and culture; thus is not solely a modern phenomenon.  Traditionally, the ideal Chinese family consisted of several children and at least one son, who was particularly important because the daughters left the household when they married.  The sons remained, taking care of the family farm, providing for elderly parents and relatives, and producing children to carry on the family name (Croll, 1985; Greenhalgh, 1994).  Families continued to have children until they had a son, labour demands in rural communities were high, and families desired as many children as they could sustain.  Over the past century, China experienced a series of uprisings, wars, epidemics and the dismantling of imperial authority during which time the annual population growth probably reached no more than 0.3%.  The gross population growth rate, however, steadily rose to around 2.8%, mostly due to falling death rates, translating into around 250 million additional people by 1970.  This expansion was seen, initially, as part of China’s increasing strength, with Mao Zedong (Chairman of ruling Chinese Communist Party from 1949 to 1976) quoted as saying that “of all things in the world, people are the most precious” (Kane, 1987: 41).  During the period of the Complex Peasant Family Model, the government was squarely focused on economic, political, and cultural issues in China.  Economically, transition to collectivism with its lack of individual ownership weakened the traditional, land-based family unit (Croll, 1985).  A number of government initiatives touched on family planning, but none had as their purpose in population control (Croll, 1985).    The population exploded from 560 million in 1949 to 810 million in 1969, and increase of almost 70% (Banister, 1987).  Part of this was due to an increase in life expectancy during the period, from below 40 to nearly 60 (Croll, 1985), due to changes in health services. As health and economic measures improved, particularly in rural communities, large families became a symbol of newfound wealth and stability.

Rapid population growth, however, did not appear to be matched by the government’s ability to cater for the basic needs of its people.  In 1970, alarmed by the implications for China’s future if the population explosion continued, the government began to advocate the Small Family Model (Croll 1985).  In 1972 the CCP formally declared the establishment of the State Family Planning Commission which advocated the key principle of “one-family, one-child” setting limits in terms of the desired rate for population growth.  Projections were that China would soon be unable to feed or economically sustain its population if growth continued (Kaufman et. al, 1989).  The Chinese government began a concerted effort to persuade families to have only one or two children.  The slogan of the campaign was “later - longer - fewer;” it encouraged young people to marry later, wait longer before having their first child, and to have fewer children in the aim of patriotism (Greenhalgh, 1994).  Population research studies had been discontinued in China in the late 1950s due to Marxist doctrine and it was only in 1975 that new university departments, staffed mainly by statisticians, began to establish themselves (Kane, 1999).  It was not long before researchers realised that with half the population aged under 21 years, it was inevitable that the population would grow, even if families remained quite small (Kane, 1999).  By the time of the census in 1982, there were already more than one billion people in China, and if contemporary trends continued, there would be 1.4 billion people by the end of the century.  Hao (1988) observes that by the early 1980s, most population growth targets were abandoned and the official objective from 1985 was to maintain the population at about 1.2 billion by the year 2000 (Kane, 1999). The results were spectacular.  The birth rates per woman dropped from six children to just under three children, while this was short of the government’s goal of 1.7 children per woman, it was a marked decrease (Greenhalgh, 1994).  For the most part the policy was accepted by the Chinese people and birth reductions were voluntary.  It is unclear why the Chinese government did not continue such a successful policy, but leaders stated that the “Small Family Model” (Croll, 1985) was ended in favour of the One Child Model so that China would achieve a secure, globally recognised economic status by the end of the millennium (Greenhalgh, 1994).

Join now!

The Chinese government, then, introduced its radical policy in 1979 requiring that urban couples limit their families to one child each.  As Fong (2004: 1) suggests, the aim of the initiative was “to help the country leapfrog from a Third-World economy into the First-World economy by mimicking First-World fertility and education patterns”.  It was hoped that third and subsequent births could be eradicated and that about a third of couples would agree to adhere to having only one child.  Feng and Hao (1992), note that strategies to discourage larger families included financial levies on each additional child and sanctions ...

This is a preview of the whole essay