Did the Nazi arms economy make war an economic necessity?

Authors Avatar

Did the Nazi arms economy make war an economic necessity?

In hindsight, the European war that started in September 1939 can seem to be the result of a logical sequence of events which, once set in motion, had an unstoppable momentum. As the steamroller careered downhill, areas were flattened and subsumed within the Reich: the Rhineland, Anschluss with Austria, the Sudetenland, Silesia, Czechoslovakia, Poland. The familiarity of the litany and its repetition in popular accounts  imbue it with an air of inevitability. However, just because it did happen, it does not follow that it had to happen in that way: traditional narrative accounts - especially popular ones - tend, in my view, to obscure the elements of contingency, chance and choice. Here, I will attempt to cast off the straitjacket of historical inevitability and start from the premise that there is no set of mechanical social and economic processes that control the destiny of politicians and nations. Rather, I will assume that there were alternative courses of action, alternative outcomes, and that economic imperatives were only one aspect of the matrix of influences that led to war. In considering this question, I will first discuss the following areas: the nature and results of the Nazi arms programme (in some detail); the place of the economy in Nazi thinking, and the wider perspective of domestic and foreign-policy making; monocratic and polycratic views of the Nazi state; and, finally, how these factors can influence our view of the war as an economic `necessity'.

The evolution of the Nazi arms economy can be traced back to the beginning of the Third Reich and Hitler's accession to the Chancelorship in January 1933, since although Hitler and the Nazis eschewed detailed economic plans and systematic measures, they set in place the basis on which subsequent economic development would be built. The immediate priority was to win the election due in March , and doing so hinged on the retention of as wide a basis of support as could be garnered. Despite the anti-capitalist cast of some Nazi propaganda, Hitler was also anxious not to `frighten the horses' in the capitalist stable . After the Nazi victory in March 1933, Reichsbank President Schact set about overcoming the still-chronic economic problems that were the legacy of the 1929 crash and the subsequent depression: 4.5 million registered unemployed, a demoralised and indebted agricultural sector, large-scale international indebtedness, regressive industrial production, collapsed incomes, and international trade that had fallen by half between 1929 and 1932 . Schact's policy rested on a kind of proto-Keynesian approach of deficit financing and the use of state expenditure to `prime the pumps' of the economy. The effects of the expansion of general state spending were significant in terms of indirect rearmament: that is, in contributing to the rehabilitation of the German economy and its economic infrastructure. The fruits of the `Reinhardt Plan' of September 1933 and of the `recovery' period of the German economy were tangible and widespread: employment was boosted through the stimulation of demand, the business cycle was revived, investment encouraged through tax concessions and subsidies, and public works schemes created the Autobahnen as well as other roads, canals, and office buildings . The general stimulus to economic regeneration can be seen in the growth of investment: from a mere 6.8 bn RM in 1933 to 10.6 bn in 1934 and 14.4 bn in 1935 . The investment in infrastructure development and in expanding the productive capacity of the economy can be seen as `indirect' rearmament in that it increased the economy's general capacity - a necessary condition of greater arms production. The explicit link between the recovery period and subsequent rearmament is adumbrated in Hitler's view, noted in February 1933, that

Join now!

The next five years in Germany had to be devoted to rendering the German people again capable of bearing arms [Wiederwehrhaftmachung]. Every publicly sponsored measure to create employment had to be considered from the point of view of whether it was necessary with respect to rendering the German people again capable of bearing arms for military service. This had to be the dominant thought, always and everywhere.  

Indeed, this was to become a dominant motif in Hitler's economic policy and will be returned to later .

In addition to the indirect rearmament, there was a parallel programme of ...

This is a preview of the whole essay