What are the changes contemplated under the ECMR. Compare and contrast them with the changes contemplated under the Enterprise Bill?

Authors Avatar

What are the changes contemplated under the ECMR. Compare and contrast them with the changes contemplated under the Enterprise Bill?

The year 2003 is witnessing important changes to the merger regimes of both the EC and the UK. While the EC introduced a reform package (consisting of amendments to the ECMR, a notice on appraising horizontal guidelines and best practice guidelines on merger proceedings) in December 2002, the UK passed the Enterprise Bill (EB), which comes into force on June 20, 2003. Whilst both these regimes are broadly similar, there are still differences between the two and it will be my endeavour to make this comparison. The comparative process itself will reveal the various changes contemplated under the ECMR reforms and the EB.

The Substantive Test for Mergers:

The main difference between the two regimes is in the substantive test employed to determine the anticompetitive nature of a merger. While the UK has now adopted the US test of “substantial lessening of competition” (SLC), the EC merger reforms make clear that the “creation or strengthening of dominance” test would continue. However in order to fill the gap found in an Airtours kind of “non co-ollusive oligopolistic” situation, the ECMR has proposed to clarify the definition of “dominance”. By an amendment to Article 2, a “dominant position” will now be deemed to arise even in a non-collusive situation, i.e. when “one or more undertakings, without co-ordinating, holds the economic power to influence appreciably and sustainably the parameters of competition, in particular, prices, production, quality of output, distribution or innovation, or appreciably to foreclose competition”. The EC has however been careful enough to ensure that this expanded test does not apply to Article 82.

The UK and Germany were sharply divided on whether to adopt the SLC test and the Commissioner Mario Monti decided to go with the German position, opining that the dominance test should be retained. This provided for more legal certainty, as this test had been in place for a long time and there was a well developed body of case law around it. Quite apart from this, various commentators were of the view that the SLC test would spur a very flexible interpretation, permitting the Commission to interfere in a wide variety of circumstances at the cost of legal certainty. As opposed to this, the “dominance” test, would, at the very least, prove to be a considerable check on the Commissions interventionist tendency. With the Commissions merger decisions being overruled by the CFI in at least three of the main cases last year (Airtours, Schneider and Tetra Laval), it is easy to see why one would be sympathetic to this view.

The merger reform package of the EC includes a notice on the appraisal of horizontal mergers, which echoes a similar expansion of the “dominance” test to fill in the Airtours gap. This notice now makes clear that the earlier two- structured approach to horizontal mergers i.e. in terms of assessing their potential anticompetitive effects under either a “unilateral effects” test (single firm dominance) or a “co-ordinated effects” test has now paved way to a tripartite classification between:

  1. a merger creating a paramount position of power (where the merged entity now holds a significant proportion of market power)
  2. a merger resulting in a collusive or co-ordinating oligopoly; and
  3. a merger resulting in a non-collusive oligopoly.

 The UK’s SLC test broadly reflects the US position, as made clear in the guidance note by the OFT. Having said the above, it could be expected that despite the differences in nomenclature, in practice, the application of these divergent tests is likely to yield the same results. This is more so as the net effect of the EC’s expanded meaning of “dominance” is to bring the EC position closer to the American substantial lessening of competition test. In fact, one of the reasons touted by the Green paper for a refusal to adopt the US test has been the fact that the application of these two different tests have produced broadly convergent results thus far. In the Commissoner, Mario Monti’s words, this indicates that there is no need to change the test and that “if it aint broke, don’t fix it”. A mere look a the Airtours decision would indicate that this statement may not be hold good in some critical cases-described my Mark Williams as “static oligopoly” cases.

Join now!

It needs to be stated here that adoption of the SLC test has been a rather critical shift for the UK which had earlier relied on a rather loose “public interest” test (though John Vickers in his speech at Oxford maintains that this criteria had been broadly interpreted to encompass only competition considerations, of the sort caught by the SLC test. In his words, despite the adoption of this test, “substantive policy” will largely remain unchanged”).

Treatment of Efficiencies:

At the level of substantive analysis of a merger, another major distinction is in the regimes’ treatment of ...

This is a preview of the whole essay