Can institutional reform effectively deal with the problem of bureaucratic corruption and inefficiency?

Authors Avatar

C. Gooden        

February, 2003

Can institutional reform effectively deal with the problem of bureaucratic corruption and inefficiency?

Public institutions that are weak and underdeveloped contribute to an environment in which corruption and other unethical behavior can thrive.  During the late 1980s and early 1990s, the word ‘audit’ began to be used with growing frequency in a wide variety of contexts.    New schemes to recognize accountability, such as Citizen’s Charters, have been created and existing entities, such as charities, have been subjected to accounting and audit reform.

        Christopher Hood (1994:17) draws a loose analogy between the extinction of the dinosaurs 60 million years ago and the apparent disappearance of a number of orthodox lines of economic policy in the 1980s.  He provides four approaches to explaining these changes in trends especially as it relates to institutional reform in the public sector, and gives general explanation for policy extinction.  Reference is made to the shift from Keynesian full-employment policy, public enterprise, ‘classical’ styles of regulation and traditional public management.  

        An institution is a society or organization that exists for the promotion of scientific, educational, or other public object.  The first rationale for what has come to be known as institutional reform or the New Public Management (NPM) is what he refers to as “climate-changing (ideological) meteorites” led by intellectual developments and changes in the world of ideas.   A second rationale was the emergence of new competitors.  This may have led to the generation of ideas that are favorable to them.  

Thirdly, a society-centred approach establishes that “old public management” had its roots in The Great Depression and world wars, where there existed mass starvation and unemployment.  The shift in policy may be explained, by a change in the societal framework of those countries that have embraced it.  Finally, Hood asserts that the failure of traditional public management may have occurred from within.  Its failure to accomplish its desired outcomes in time led to the search for a new style of governance.

             Instances of corruption around the world are reported on almost a daily basis.  There is no scarcity of scandals that illustrate the depth and pervasiveness of corruption: the shady funding of political parties in Europe and North America, bribes to high-level officials for major export contracts in many countries, the depletion of health insurance funds in Argentina, the plundering of national assets in Russia, and the endemic confusion between private and public funds in some developing countries and transition economies. Expediting the provision of birth certificates, passports and driver’s licenses and nepotism in appointments and promotions in the Civil Service, may have led to the recent article in the Gleaner that noted that corruption will continue to be prevalent in Jamaica unless civil servants are paid higher salaries.

The definitional aspect of corruption is rather problematic and has occupied large parts of many papers on political corruption. Moreover, the object of defining corruption is highly dependent on the perspective from which it is viewed. The legal definition of corruption is an act done with the intent to give some advantage inconsistent with official duty and the rights of others. It includes bribery, but is more comprehensive; because an act may be corruptly done, though the advantage to be derived from it may not be offered by another.
Rose-Ackerman contends, “Corruption is a symptom that something has gone wrong in the management of the state”.  Sometimes corruption is understood as an act against the law, such as, a contract by which the borrower agreed to pay the lender usurious interest. It is said, in such a case, that it was corruptly agreed.

Although corruption is largely attributed to government and the public sector, it also prevails in the private sector.   The key factor in determining organizational performance is not whether it is publicly or privately owned but how it is organized and managed. In practice, most public sector organizations have transformed their processes far below expectations, both in terms of economic indicators and social goals, raising questions about their efficacy as positive instruments for economic and social progress.

  Corruption can be viewed from a number of perspectives. The main ones are: the moralist-normative, the functionalist, the public office-legalist, the public interest-institutionalist, and the interest maximizing.  To explain two very contrasting views, the moralist-normative perspective defines corruption as inherently bad, as a lack of moral commitment among officials and focuses on the detrimental effects of corruption on public trust of officials.   The functionalist perspective views corruption as an ever- present quality of every society.  In their view the moralist perspective is of Western construct. Corruption serves to accelerate processes in an in-efficient bureaucracy.  

Join now!

Corruption is present in all societies but some are more damaged by it than others. It erodes public confidence in political institutions and leads to contempt for the rule of law.  Corruption distorts the allocation resources, inflates public procurement and undermines competition.  Nonetheless societal definitions of what constitute a corrupt act may vary.  

        Assessing the organizational efficiency of the public sector is also quite difficult.  First, unlike private organizations, public organizations have no single performance indicator – such as profits or market share – that can be used to compare across different types of organizations or products.  Few organizations ...

This is a preview of the whole essay