Price discounts and michelin: What goes around, comes around.

Authors Avatar

PRICE DISCOUNTS AND MICHELIN: WHAT GOES AROUND, COMES AROUND

So, 20 years on, we now have Michelin, the sequel. Those who read the first decision may not wish to dwell too long on the second--all the same analytical short-comings are present: the failure to acknowledge complexity, the apparent lack of any real understanding of the business world, the lack of any acceptance by the Commission of the need to fine-tune its regulatory intervention in the area of competition law which cries out for it more, perhaps, than any other. The issue is not whether the main Commission decisions are right or wrong; it is the lack of analysis of the real competitive context in which the impugned pricing behaviour takes place and the likely effects of that behaviour on prices and output.

The purpose of this article is to examine the Commission's position in its own terms, focusing on its purest manifestation, and suggesting that whatever the merits of, and prognosis for, the E.U. approach to the price discount area more generally, certain aspects of the Commission's approach (at the very least) are likely to change.

Michelins 1 and 2

In November 1981, the European Commission decided Michelin. [FN1] This was the second major E.C. case on discount schemes operated by dominant firms, after Hoffmann-La Roche [FN2] in the 1970s. The schemes involved a complex system of discounts to dealers in replacement tyres for trucks and buses in the Netherlands; they were prohibited, and the Commission was upheld in the European Court of Justice (ECJ) two years later. The Commission and the ECJ were criticised at the time for the lack of depth of their analysis.

On May 31, 2002, the Commission published Michelin 2. [FN3] Like the first decision, the facts involve discount schemes to dealers in new replacement tyres (and retreaded tyres) for trucks and buses, this time in France. Again, the schemes are complex and are set out by the Commission in meticulous detail. Again, however, the care devoted to this exercise is in stark contrast to the simplicity of the analysis which follows it.

It is perhaps appropriate that Michelin is about replacement tyres. One could replace Michelin 1 with Michelin 2 in the Commission's precedent bank and it would scarcely be noticed. The Commission has reminded us in this case that while a kind of revolution has been taking place in other parts of competition law (relaxation of vertical restraints policy, modernisation, economic approach to market definition and anti-competitive effects), Article 82 pricing regulation is alive and well and has not moved significantly forward in 20 years.

Commission's treatment of the Michelin schemes

My present purpose is not to provide a full commentary on the Michelin case, but it is necessary to describe some of the key factors of the schemes. Michelin appears to have had a market share in the supply of new replacement tyres for heavy vehicles in France of somewhere in the region of 60 per cent.

There were various different schemes, and different features were emphasised in respect of each one:

• The principal bonus appears to have been a quantity rebate, with the same volume thresholds applicable to all dealers. Michelin pleaded the transparency of this system, contrasting the lack of transparency of the schemes condemned in the first case, but the Commission held that lack of transparency was not a necessary ingredient of abuse. The scheme contained a feature condemned in the 1999 Virgin/British Airways decision: that payment of any rebate was to be made over all sales "rolled back to unit one", i.e. that the percentage rebate for hitting the target is paid on all sales achieved in the relevant reference period, and not just on a tranche of incremental sales.

• The "service bonus "scheme, on the other hand, was highlighted for the margin of discretion it afforded to Michelin (in the Commission's view) and the fact that, during the first year of the alleged infringement, the basis for reward was the share which Michelin represented of a dealer's sales, i.e. more of a direct reward for winning business from competitors.

• The "progress bonus" scheme was highlighted for its "year on year" basis, i.e. the reward depended on the dealer increasing his purchases of Michelin products compared to his purchases the previous year (again a feature picked out in British Airways).

Other features highlighted by the Commission included:

• the combination of low margins (3.7 per cent) and back payment of rebates, which according to the Commission meant that dealers suffered cash flow losses and uncertainty/insecurity pending payment of rebates;

• the one year reference period, i.e. the period of time over which purchases are measured against the targets; this was seen as too long (see below);

• the fact that one of the schemes involved as many as 18 "steps", where each step means another rebate, or an increased rebate, is achieved; according to the Commission in this particular passage, more steps is worse for competition;

• the "first retread" clause whereby extra bonus was earned if all Michelin tyres purchased were sent to Michelin for retreading, as although Michelin said this was not enforced in practice, it was regarded by the Commission as exclusivity; and

• the fact that more tyres were retreaded in France than were sold in France-- which the Commission saw as evidence that Michelin must be retreading competitors' tyres as well as its own.

In summary, according to the Commission, Michelin had for 20 or so years [FN4]:

pursued a commercial policy in France with regard to resellers which was based on a complex system of rebates, discounts and/or various financial benefits whose main objective was to tie resellers to it and to maintain its market shares, which must be regarded as an abuse within the meaning of Article 82. [FN5]

The Commission reserved special condemnation for the arrangements of the "Michelin Friends" club; these included certain obligations on Michelin's large dealer members, in return for additional financial payments. For example:

• they were obliged to carry a sufficient stock of Michelin products to be able to respond immediately to customer requirements; the Commission concludes that stocks would have to match Michelin's existing share of a dealer's purchases, and that this would deter dealers from increasing their purchase of competing brands;

• they agreed to disclose to Michelin certain statistics and sales forecasts which, the Commission concludes, meant that the dealer could never decide to sell competing products without Michelin being aware of this; and

• they were obliged not to divert "spontaneous demand" away from Michelin tyres; the Commission says this became in some cases an obligation effectively to maintain a certain market share (or "Michelin temperature", as it was known). [FN6]

To this the Commission adds an atmospheric observation:

the members of the Club all shared the feeling that there could be no turning back ... The commitment they had entered into could fairly be described as a lifetime one. [FN7]

Commentary on Michelin: superficial reasoning and internal contradiction

Two preliminary observations may be made. First, the precise attributes of each scheme are not catalogued in any clear way by the Commission; one has to search different parts of the decision to piece them together. This is an immediate sign that beyond a certain point the details are not particularly relevant in the Commission's eyes. Secondly, some of the features picked out by the Commission as exacerbating the loyalty effect go in the opposite direction to the one usually considered harmful to competition. Thus, back payment of rebates is condemned, and yet up-front payment is usually considered more heinous because the dealer has then, as it were, already banked the money, and is incentivised to avoid having to find it again to pay it back. Multiple steps are condemned, and yet the usual criticism is that a few steps with big jumps have a greater tying effect as the dealer approaches each step. Multiple steps start to look like a line which makes it easier for competitors to persuade a dealer to "get off" at any one point.

Join now!

All of this goes to illustrate the psychology of the Commission in these cases: it is like a parent opening a door to a child's messy room: it does not like what it sees, the verdict is determined immediately and amassing the evidence to support the verdict is just a question of picking up any combination of the items on display.

The passage on the friends club is extraordinary. The Commission makes the dealer members sound like prisoners at the mercy of their captors. The so- called "obligations" were in fact agreed in return for even greater discounts, but we ...

This is a preview of the whole essay