A single currency also eliminates all the transaction costs associated with converting money between all the various currencies that were previously in circulation, which should allow for a greater mobility of labour as workers, particular for workers located close to national boundaries as they would be able to take jobs either side of that boarder and be paid in their ‘home’ currency. The abolition on ‘red tape’ surrounding getting a job in another country would also have had a big impact in this area though, and it has been shown that labour migration in the Euro zone is still mush less than, say in the USA, a ‘zone’ of similar size and population. Factors behind this could be the much wider variety of regional variation in Europe compared to America in terms of culture, customs and not least language.
Alternatively, though, the introduction of a single currency could hit employment in some regions of the Euro zone due the restrictions placed on monetary policy alluded to in the opening paragraph. A topical example of this in recent years is Germany, who has been suffering from high unemployment rates and ‘high’ interest rates. To rectify their problem, in the days of the Deutsche Mark, they would simply have lowered interest rates to increase spending and stimulate their economy, but now this is an option unavailable to them. The problem is that other areas of the zone, the Netherlands say have high unemployment rates, and ideally what their economy would require is a high interest rate to dampen the economy. Neither country has autonomous control of their money supply and the ECB (European Central Bank) has to set rates such as best match the needs of the region as a whole, not just individual economies.
There are many different types of unemployment that can occur throughout the euro zone. Frictional unemployment occurs commonly throughout the workforce. It comprises of people that or temporally out of work as they are looking for a new job. Structural unemployment can cause more problems within different states in the euro zone than the area as a whole. This is due to major movements of industries throughout the zone, in search of cheaper labour. It can cause a miss-match to the location of the job and the location of the workers. Cyclical unemployment arises when the demand for employment is in decline, caused by a business cycle recession. Classical unemployment occurs as the national minimum wage is above the true market clearing price. However classical unemployment can really be seen. Technological and structural unemployment occurs as machines are used to replace the human workforce and as seasonal demand dictates the demand for unemployment.
The claimant count is one method of measuring unemployed, simply by counting the number of people claiming unemployment benefits. However the major problem with such figures is that many people would consider themselves unemployed but would not be allowed to claim benefits, or others maybe simply would not claim benefits for one reason or another. Many people also saw the claimant count as been rather open to government manipulation.
The labour force survey measure is comprised of the percentage of 15-64 year olds who are in paid employment excluding those who live in ‘collective households’ (such as halls of residence). Due to this the actual figures quoted are the employment rates in each country. To be officially classed as unemployed, people must have actively sought work in the 4 weeks previous to the survey being carried out and must be ‘currently’ available to take a job (Economics Update 2001, 7).
The data I have is based on the Labour Force Survey
The Euro Zone consists of the 12 countries who had adopted the currency by 31 December 2005 which were Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain and Greece.
For comparison, I have included figures for the full Euro area, the EU25, which incorporates the 12 Euro Zone countries as well as The Czech Republic, Denmark, Cyprus, Latvia, Lithuania, Hungary, Malta, Poland, Slovenia, Slovakia, Sweden, The UK and Bulgaria.
As the graph on the previous page indicates, the unemployment rate for the Euro zone does drop, (as the employment rate on the graphs rise) but how much of this drop can we attribute to the Euro? As the unemployment rate also drops in the EU25 as a whole. From the graph, it is clear to see though that unemployment drops furthest in those countries that did adopt the Euro. To emphasise this point I calculated the change in employment rate in all those countries that had adopted the Euro and then in the countries that haven’t adopted the Euro.
The above table illustrates how the employment rate rose by an average of 2.71% in all those countries making up the Euro zone, however some individual countries did rather better than others, such as Spain with a 9.5% rise compared to Germany with only a 0.2 increase and Austria’s that was unchanged over the period as a whole. This data would seem to point towards the Euro having a positive impact on unemployment rates, especially when we consider the table on the following page, showing the average changes in employment rates for the EU25 countries that did not adopt the Euro. Here we find an average change of only 0.98% in employment rates over the same 7 year period (although data is only available for 6 years for a few countries). Some countries, Czech Republic, Denmark, Malta, Poland and Slovakia, even register negative growth over the period.
This data overall would tend to suggest that the Euro is indeed responsible in some extent for the fall in unemployment witnessed in the EU since its introduction in 1999.
(All tables and figures adapted from epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu)