How far has the creation of a single market in goods resulted in the limitation of powers of community member states in the field of commercial activity?

Authors Avatar

How far has the creation of a single market in goods resulted in the limitation of powers of community member states in the field of commercial activity?

                                                                

Introduction

Free movement of goods is a fundamental part of the single market, although goods have never been defined by the EC treaty, it was left sufficiently vague so as to encompass many products ”which shall cover all goods. The principle of movement of goods has been described as the “corner stone” of the community as defined in Article 14 originally Article 8a of the EEC Treaty:

An area without internal frontiers in which the free movement of goods, persons, services and capital is ensured in accordance with the provisions of this treaty"

The underlying objective permeating through the main provisions of the community concerning free movement of goods political integration. The phrase ‘single market’ or ‘internal market’ replaced the term ‘common market’ by the Single European Act 1986. The primary reason why states joined the community was because of the benefits and exposure it would give their goods in the internal market, a market free of internal restriction on trade. The philosophy behind the free market was that market forces compete in the world market increasing economic efficiency. This philosophy of included in its definition, products originating from third countries. This can be seen in Article 23. 

The policy of free movement of goods is based on a concept of a customs union.  The EC Treaty strives to seek a customs union under Article 23 (ex Article 9) which means in effect prohibition between member states on customs duties and the adoption of a customs tariff in relations with third countries. It also seeks to eliminate quantitative restrictions on imports and exports and all measures having equivalent effect, Articles 28 and 29. States also have to ensure that discrimination does not exist concerning the procurement of goods between national of member states as in Article 31 (ex article 37). In terms of state monopolies of a commercial character 

Generally freedom of goods applies to goods produced within the community and those from outside the community which are in free circulation, this can be seen in Article 23 and Article 10 (1). Goods or products are not defined in the Treaty, therefore the courts have found difficulty in defining what goods or products are also there have been problems where products have been produced in various countries therefore the problem of origination occurs. In the case of Commission v. Italy, this case attempted to establish whether the Italian Government where in breach of Article 16 of the EEC when they continued to levy progressive taxes on the export to other Member States of Community products having “artistic, historical, archaeological or ethnographic value”. Italy attempted to argue that the goods where not consumer goods or products of general use and not therefore subject to the provision of the Treaty which applied to ordinary merchandise. The court pointed out that Article 9 (new Article 23) that the community “is based on a customs union which shall cover all trade in goods

All goods within the community are in free circulation. This includes products outside the community. Free circulation entails removal of all barriers to this freedom of movement of goods which includes customs duties, any charges having equivalent effect; physical and technical barriers; discriminatory internal taxation; and state monopolies which will be discussed individually.

Derogations from restrictions also limit the principle of free movement of goods, eg  A.30, which allows derogation from the restrictions of Articles 28 & 29.  Free movement of goods may also be restricted by Article 134 which states that when economic difficulties arise individual Member States may take preventative action. Free movement of goods can also be restricted by Member States national security Article 296 and 297. Also a Member State may obstruct the functioning of the common market if there is a threat if maintenance of law and order.

This notion of customs union and in particular prohibition of customs duties is noted in Article 25.

According to the spirit, the general scheme and the wording of the Treaty, Article 12 must be interpreted as producing direct effects and creating individual rights which national courts must protect. Apart from Customs duties there are charges having equivalent effect in practice the effect of such charges is no different to those of customs duties. 

                                                                

Taxation.

The free movement of goods has as its objective of the internal market the removal of all “obstacles to the free circulation of goods between member states”.  Thus customs duties and taxes need to be defined and monitored so as to allow free circulation of goods within the community.

When goods enter the community from third countries the common external tariff (CET) applies.  Governed by Articles 23-27 detailed rules are set out relating to classification of third country goods and duties to be charged on entry in the community.  Once the duty is paid, goods can then be freely circulated throughout the community.

Articles 81-97 of the Treaty are aimed at eliminating measures that restrict trade between member states.  Article 25; the standstill provision prohibits introduction by states, new customs duties having equivalent effect on imports, exports and increasing existing duties.

A customs duty is a tax or levy imposed on goods because they cross a frontier.  

In the Gingerbread case, Luxembourg and Belgium increased charges imposed on the imports of gingerbread.  It was done so as to offset the effects on the price of domestically produced  gingerbread of an internal tax on rye, a gingerbread ingredient.  It was held that such a charge altered the price of gingerbread and reduced its competitiveness which affected trade between member states.  The measure was thereby a “charge having equivalent effect” (a CEE) as under article 25 and frustrated the objectives of a single market.  Effectively this charge had similar effect to a customs duty, which article 25 prohibits.

Member states often argue charges imposed on imported goods escape article 25 prohibition because they are for services rendered to the importer such as a quality control inspection service.  The ECJ will only allow a service outside the article 25 prohibition if the service is directly beneficial to the traders and the charge is proportionate to the service provided.  In the case of Rewe-Zentralfinanz it was held that where an inspection service is imposed in the ‘general interest’ it cannot be regarded as a service rendered to justify the imposition of a charge.  Only when a service is mandatory under EC law will the states be allowed to cover the cost of the service.

Taxes imposed on imported goods, such as those levied by member states as part of a system of internal taxation may also be viewed as an obstacle to free movement.  If a charge is a genuine internal tax rather than a customs duty or CEE then article 25 will not apply, it will fall within article 90.  This prohibits the discriminatory taxation of imported and domestically produced goods.

Internal taxation of any kind on imports in excess of that imposed directly or indirectly on similar domestic products is prohibited under article 90(1).  Other connected factors to taxation may also be viewed as discriminatory such as the rules relating to tax collection.

Direct discrimination; where tax provisions openly treat imported and domestic goods differently is often avoided by member states as it is easily identifiable.  Indirect discrimination involves cases where the taxation system appears neutral but effectively discriminates against imported products.  In Humblot car taxation indirectly put imported cars at a competitive disadvantage because all cars of that category were imported into France.

Much case law has focused upon the issue of ‘similar products’ as article 90(1) ensures different products can be taxed at different rates.  The ECJ has held however, that the term ‘similar products’ should be interpreted widely to encompass similar characteristics and use.

Article 90(2) prohibits indirect protection given through internal taxation to domestic products that are in competition with imported products.

Problems arising from discriminatory taxation can be solved by harmonizing taxation between member states.  However member states are reluctant to give power to the community in an area that symbolises national sovereignty.

Taxes imposed on imported goods, customs duties and CEEs may be regarded as an obstacle to the free movement of goods as they increase the traders costs.  They may also raise the price of products to the consumer; affecting the competitive structure of the internal market.  It is for this reason that the EC monitors the situation of taxes throughout member states in Europe so that goods can move freely between states as the  EC Treaty intended.  In doing so states’ powers have to be limited, in order for their taxes to be waivered to allow goods to be imported and exported between countries.

Quantitative Restrictions, Measures having equivalent effect and the Principles of

Cassis de Dijon

In accordance with the EC philosophy of a single market Articles 28 and 29 prohibit the use of non-pecuniary measures introduced by member states, which restrict free movement of goods.  Quantitative restrictions are prohibited on both exports and imports. as are measures deemed to have equivalent effect to quantitative restrictions (MEQRs). These are split into 2 categories. They can be 'distinctly applicable' in that they directly relate to member states dealings with each other through exports and imports. However, they can also be 'indistinctly applicable' in that they can apply to exports, imports or domestic goods deemed to impose quantitative restrictions on other member states ability to freely trade. Herein lies the potentially great limit on Member states powers in commercial activity. Domestic commercial measures are being examined and restricted. Even if they can be justified in terms of their domestic purpose, the Court and Commission have devised formulas and tests to judge whether these domestic measures breach Articles 28 & 29 and if so whether they are justified to do so. The degree of limit on state powers in commercial activity appears to lie in their hands. What is the impact of this and how great are the limits imposed?

Join now!

Dealing first with imports, A.28 Treaty of Rome states that,

"Quantitative restrictions on imports and MEQRs shall be prohibited between member states".

An example of a quantitative restriction prohibited can be found in R v Henn in which a ban on importing pornographic material was found to be in breach of the article. This example shows a measure that clearly effects the ability of another Member State to move a certain variety of goods, and so was prohibited. However, Steiner feels the reference to MEQRs is much "wider in scope".

A distinctly applicable measure also appears to be a ...

This is a preview of the whole essay