To what extent did the 'collective' farms of Eastern Europe work?

Authors Avatar

To what extent did the ‘collective’ farms of Eastern Europe work?

The ideology of collectivisation 1st became a viable policy in Stalinist Russia. The primary thinking behind this revolutionary initiative was to improve agricultural production to a level that could sustain the ever-increasing urban masses. Furthermore the decision makers in Eastern Europe wished to ensure an abundant supply of cheap food was available so that they could control, and keep real wage rates at a manageable level. The collectivisation of agriculture was envisaged by the socialist regimes as the “Ideal vehicle to achieve this objective.” (1) The large-scale cultivation necessitated by collectivisation was seen by the socialist regime as a fundament strategy to improve the total productivity of the agricultural sector.

Within a short space of time its origins and principles had began to spread rapidly throughout the Eastern European states, until the widespread adoption of the policy became an essential tool for the majority of socialist regimes.

As one looks at collectivisation throughout Eastern Europe, it becomes apparent early on that no 2 nation states had identical results from the adoption of this policy. Each State has to be judged on its own merits and individual socio-economic results.

Hungary, Poland and Czechoslovakia were 3 infant states that had collectivisation enforced upon them by the expansionist German regime. In the immediate aftermath of the war they simultaneously decided that they would progress with the ‘cooperative farm’ ethos that the Nazi government had installed in their societies.  It had shown a level of effectiveness and efficiency that when manipulated can have huge governmental benefits.  

The Hungarian collectivisation policy applied the majority of its focus on the grain producing regions. The government believed that if they prioritised on a particular strain of harvest, then they would reap the rewards through increased efficiency and productivity levels.  This policy never really came to fruition, primarily because the absurd quota levels being enforced on the cooperatives made for a distinct disincentive among the peasantry.  This issue was further enhanced when in 1952 it was found that approximately 800,000 peasants were without sufficient grain to make bread or even sow a new crop.

After the ill-fated Nagy regime abolished compulsory collectivisation, calling on the fact that the lack of economic incentive to the individual peasant made it an ill conceived policy.  This move led to the dissolution of 60% of all cooperatives between June and December of 1956.

It was not until the Kadar administration came to power that Hungarian agriculture began to show a return for its investment and endeavour.  Kadar instigated a reformed version of collectivisation. He removed the element of class structure that was predominant in the Stalinist version. Instead he replaced this with a concerted effort to win the approval of the middle peasantry. Kadar was working from the assumption that if he could inflict his views on the middle peasantry, then the rest of the Village would fall into line and follow their example.  On latter inspections the strategy that Kadar implemented seems full proof. Even if the middle peasants refused to join governmental orientated cooperatives, they were encouraged to form their own, which many evidently did.

The outcome of Kadar’s reformed collectivisation policy was astounding. The percentage of agriculture area socialised increased from, 34% in 1952, to 97% in 1962.  This was the largest percentage that any of the socialist Eastern European countries have ever assembled either prior to this period in question or to this very day.

Join now!

I believe that the overwhelming reason for the success of this policy was fundamentally due to the welfare reforms implemented within the new system.  The very fact that health insurance and a pension scheme were incorporated into the strategy, and also the generous level of state subsidies to improve capital and machinery meant that it would be in every peasant’s best interest to join such a scheme.  This approach enabled Hungarian collectivisation to be completed by 1961, only 3 years after the policy was initiated.  

The Polish governments experience of collectivisation was minimal to say the least. ...

This is a preview of the whole essay