Societal Growth Rates

At least up to the early 1980's the orthodox theory of economic growth was Solow's neoclassical model which involved an exogenously determined long-run rate of growth and hence predicted convergence of growth rates between countries. However, widespread convergence has clearly not occurred, something that -among other things- caused dissatisfaction with the orthodox view and led to the emergence of the New Growth Theories. These made the rate of growth endogenous and as we will see allowed for non-convergence and even for divergence of income levels and growth rates between countries so the opposite from the essay title is true.

A brief account of the neoclassical model would be useful. It assumes that only one good is produced, all savings are automatically invested, factor prices are flexible (i.e. there is no independent investment function), universal perfect competition and the aggregate production function conforms to the "Inada conditions" which among other things require that we have constant returns to scale and diminishing returns to either of the factors of production by themselves. Technology is assumed to be exogenous though it is easy to incorporate labour augmenting or Harrod neutral technical change In any case the conclusion of the model is that since (with labour and technology exogenous) investment (I) in capital (K) exhibits diminishing returns, any change in the rate of investment will have only a temporary effect in the growth rate -though it will have a permanent effect in income level- since eventually the marginal productivity of K will fall to zero. In fact, as the marginal product of I continues to fall, the savings generated by the income accruing to new K will also fall so the I rate will decline until it will only be just sufficient to replace worn-out machines and equip new workers. We, thus, have exogenous growth, determined by the also exogenous population growth and technological progress.

As far as convergence is concerned, it depends what assumptions we make about woldwide technological spillovers and K mobility. The most common assumptions attributed to the neoclassical model is that technology is universally available but we have no -or imperfect- capital mobility. In this case, growth rates will be equated, though not necessarily income per capita. This is so because poor countries with a lower K stock have higher rates of return on I. So if a country has a lower propensity to save and hence to invest, its relative income and K stock will decline until the return to I in that country increases so much its growth rate eventually equals the high I country. Actually the increased return on I will increase I so the equilibrium income differential will not be as big; though this may be counterbalanced by the low saving ratios that poor economies near the level of subsistence may have.

If we assume both technological diffusion and perfect capital mobility then convergence in both growth rates and income levels should be almost instantaneous since it means that domestic saving and I are uncorrelated : Capital would flow from the rich-high K-low returns economy to the poor-low K-high returns one until the returns are equalised, i.e. until they have the same income/K stock. In fact the optimal rate of Current Account Deficit was found to be equal to the level of I with a market rate of return. If we have perfect K mobility but imperfect technological diffusion then no convergence needs to occur -even divergence may occur- but it is difficult to have such a case within the neoclassical model since it is hard to reconcile perfect capital mobility with imperfect technological spillovers, especially given the model's view of technology.

The evidence as we have said, did not conform to the neocl. predictions as growth rates have shown significant variations both through time and between countries with little signs of convergence occurring. On the other hand, it has been argued that 3 groups of countries can be identified -rich, intermediate and poor- and that convergence exists inside these groups but not between them. This could in fact be compatible with the neocl. model if we recognise that technology moves freely between the rich countries but only imperfectly so between the rich and less developed countries. This was recognised by Solow who argued that introduction of such things like political instability could make the growth rate endogenous and explain non-convergence. Barro has also pointed out the importance of political stability but as we will see later on in a rather different context.

We could also mention here the "traverse perspective", associated with Hicks and Lowe, which by concerning itself with the transition phase from one steady growth to another, allows the neoclassical model to break away from many of their restrictive assumptions. In this approach the non-convergence could simply be a medium-term adjustment to the neocl. steady state. Nevertheless, this begs the question of how long this adjustment takes while since a dynamic economy is always in a traverse, pinpointing the equilibrium point can be problematic to such an extent that it may ultimately render irrelevant the neocl. theory. Furthermore, the problem with the neocl. model is not only it does not fit the evidence but that it is incomplete since, among other things, we "know" that technology (and pop. growth?) are not exogenous. Few would subscribe to the view that technology is solely driven by science which in turn proceeds at a pace and direction independent from economic conditions and incentives.

The New Growth theories are a fairly heterogeneous collection of models but they all have in common the endogenous determination of the long-run growth rate by abandoning the assumption of constant returns with respect to the use of (physical) K and labour together and assuming instead increasing returns to a broad measure of K which includes things like knowledge or public infrastructure. Increasing returns are of course incompatible with perfect competition but the viability of perfect competition is preserved by making knowledge a social factor of production so each individual firm faces const. returns. This means that knowledge is under- provided so we have an externality which justifies government intervention to correct it, in particular given that now govt. policies can permanently affect the long-run rate of growth. The role of the govt. in helping growth is a huge and controversial issue I don't want to get into here, but it should be noted that most New Growth theorists are relatively reluctant to advocate widespread govt. intervention, partly because of fear of govt. failure and partly because New growth theory could even be interpreted as a demand for less rather than more govt. intervention in the sense of low tax rates and no crowding out of private I.

Join now!

The New Growth theories are often distinguished in two main types depending on the way they incorporate knowledge: The first type is akin to Arrow's (1962) "learning by doing" models who was one of the first to attempt to render technical progress endogenous. Arrow recognised that learning by doing may enhance productivity and argued that it is related with cumulative gross I because I changes the environment and provides stimulate for learning. The effect of learning by doing on productivity is external to an individual firm, thus allowing perfect competition. The long-run rate of growth, however, remained exogenous because Arrow ...

This is a preview of the whole essay