• Join over 1.2 million students every month
  • Accelerate your learning by 29%
  • Unlimited access from just £6.99 per month

What ended hyperinflation in Germany, Austria and Hungary in the 1920s? Do the facts support the Rational Expectation Hypothesis?

Extracts from this document...

Introduction

EC313 International Economic Systems Topic: What ended hyperinflation in Germany, Austria and Hungary in the 1920s? Do the facts support the Rational Expectation Hypothesis? After World War I, the pressure of wartime finance forced belligerents such as Germany, Austria and Hungary off the gold standard, which had served in the prewar period to stabilize price movements. These countries resorted to large-scale borrowing and the printing of paper money to finance the war reparation and this caused severe hyperinflations in 1920s, resulted dislocation in both national and international economies. To end the hyperinflation, these countries made some deliberate changes in their monetary and fiscal policies. In this paper, I will analyze policy changes in Germany, Austria and Hungary separately. Furthermore, expectations play a central role in hyperinflations. Under rational expectations, economic agents respond to credible changes in government policy by altering their strategies. So a correctly perceived change in policy regime can end inflation without large real effects on the economy such as output and unemployment. In this paper, I also interpret whether the facts of hyperinflations in these countries consist with the Rational Expectation Hypothesis respectively. I. Germany The most important force for Germany's hyperinflation is the fact that Germany owed staggering reparations to the Allied countries. From August 1922 to November 1923, prices rose 355% per month and the note circulation of the Reichsbank increased dramatically. ...read more.

Middle

The central bank was forbidden for lending to the government except on the security of an equal amount of gold and foreign assets. Note issues of the bank were backed by minimal proportions of gold, foreign assets and commercial bills. Furthermore, the bank was obligated to resume convertibility into gold once the government's debt reduced to 30 million gold crowns. The new currency schilling, which is equal to ten thousand paper crowns, was introduced at the end of 1924. Moreover, there was a commissioner general from the Council of the League of Nations to monitor Austria's commitments for financial reconstruction. The Reparation Commission also modified its claim on the government resource of Austria. Other than these monetary reforms, balanced budget was achieved by several actions within two years. Like the Germans, thousands of government employees were discharged to reduce expenditures. Prices of government-sold goods and services were raised to reduce deficits of government enterprises. New taxes were introduced and the power of government to collect taxes was much stronger. Figure 2 shows that the stabilization of crown was accompanied by a drastic increase in the unemployment rate, although the unemployment rate already started to increase before the stabilization. The number of unemployment benefits claims increased dramatically after the termination of the hyperinflation, from 38000 in October 1922 to 117000 in January 1923. ...read more.

Conclusion

However, It was generally agreed that hyperinflation in Germany did not support this hypothesis. Reference Thomas J. Sargent, Chapter 3, The end of four big inflations, Rational Expectations and Inflation, 2nd ed. Wicker Elmus, Terminating hyperinflation in the dismembered Hapsburg Monarchy, American Economic Review, June 1986 Balderston T, War finance and inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914-1918, Economic History Review, 1989 Phillip Cagan, Expectations in the German hyperinflation reconsidered, Journal of International Money and Finance, 1991, 10, pp 552-560 Thomas J. Sargent, The demand for money during hyperinflations under rational expectations, International Economic Review, Vol. 18. 1, February 1977 Hamid Beladi, Munit A. S. Choudhary, Amar K. Parai, Rational and adaptive expectations in the present value model of hyperinflation, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75.3, August 1993, pp 511-514 Thomas J. Sargent, Neil Wallace, Rational expectations and the dynamics of hyperinflation, International Economic Review, Vol. 14.2, June 1973, pp 328-350 Michael K. Salemi, Adaptive expectations, rational expectations and money demand in hyperinflation Germany, Journal of Monetary Economics, 5, 1979, pp 593-604 Rondo Cameron, Larry Neal, Chapter 14, International Economic Disintegration, pp 338-348, A Concise Economic History of the World: from Paleolithic Times to the Present, 4th ed, Oxford University Press Appendix Figure 1 Source: Converted from table in Graham (1930, p 287) Figure 2 Source: Converted from table in League of Nations (1926, p 87) Figure 3 Source: Converted from Table 8 in Wicker 1 ...read more.

The above preview is unformatted text

This student written piece of work is one of many that can be found in our AS and A Level Macroeconomics section.

Found what you're looking for?

  • Start learning 29% faster today
  • 150,000+ documents available
  • Just £6.99 a month

Not the one? Search for your essay title...
  • Join over 1.2 million students every month
  • Accelerate your learning by 29%
  • Unlimited access from just £6.99 per month

See related essaysSee related essays

Related AS and A Level Macroeconomics essays

  1. Comparing the effects of immigration on GDP in Malaysia, Japan and South Africa.

    So, the immigrants are the additional source of income to the government by getting a higher tax income. 7.1.1 Advantages on Economy of Japan Japan is an "economic miracle country" because it has developed very fast after World War II.

  2. Budget 2004-05 and Economic Analysis of Pakistan

    TOTAL: 645234 714019 700770 Under the New Chart of Accounts, the bulk of expenditure has been booked under General Public Service. The expenditure against this head has been budgeted at Rs 423836 million as compared with Rs 448430 million in the revised estimates and Rs 377926 million in the budget estimates of 2003-2004 .

  1. Unemployment Issues in Germany

    And not only do the United States and Germany share many cultural similarities but they are also deeply economically interdependent, 8.8% of all German exports are U.S. bound. Like many other export oriented countries, Germany itself does not have the climate or the natural resources necessary to support a high

  2. How Were the Lives of Germans Affected by the Hyper-Inflation of 1923?

    The middle class were possibly the hardest hit as they were the most likely to have had savings - which were wiped out, and they tended to be proffessionals who depended on cash payments but whose services were in less demand during this crisis; doctors, teachers and lawyers amongst these, they sold furniture, clothing, works of art to buy food.

  1. Inflation in Germany

    All they have left her is a Mark with which to cover her nakedness. The fact that the Mark does not completely cover her nakedness represents how useless the Mark was at that period. This source was published in 1923 when inflation was at its peak.

  2. Governments set economic objectives - Discuss the relative importance of each of these objectives ...

    there is an inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment]. This meant that it was impossible to have low levels of unemployment and low levels in changes in money wages at the same time. The trend he identified became known as the "Phillips" Curve.

  • Over 160,000 pieces
    of student written work
  • Annotated by
    experienced teachers
  • Ideas and feedback to
    improve your own work