Elements of Art. 81

Authors Avatar

Art. 81

  • Art. 81 is a fundamental provision which is essential for the accomplishment of the tasks entrusted to the Community and, in particular, the functioning of the internal market.
  • Single market concerns have played a crucial part in the development of the Court’s jurisprudence and sometimes this formalistic approach has been to the detriment of economic efficiency considerations.
  • In interpreting the provision the Court adopts a teleological approach construing Community acts in accordance with the broad system of Treaty aims and objectives set out in Art 2 and 3.
  • An appreciation of the tension between market integration and economic efficiency, and the close relationship between competition rules and the free movement of goods begins with the Court’s seminal judgment in Etablissements Consten SA and Grundig v Commission.

It confirms that market integration lies at the heart of art. 81. Art 81 does not only apply to horizontal but also to vertical agreements.

Critics of the judgment consider that the existence of market power ids the real issue and argue that inter-brand competition would prevent Grundig’s products from being sold at a high price.

In Societe Technique Miniere the Court confirmed that market analysis is not necessary where the object of the agreement is clearly to restrict competition.

Elements of Art. 81

Undertakings

  • This will include any natural or legal person carrying on a commercial activity in the goods and services sector. The Court has consistently held that the term has the same meaning in both 81 and 82 (i.a. Flat Glass).
  • Hoefner and Elser v Macroton: “every entity engaged in an economic activity regardless of the legal status of the entity and the way in which it is financed”, even in the absence of a profit motive.
  • The definition does extend to public authorities if the entity does carry out functions of an economic nature or performs an essential function of the state. However, an entity, public or private, which performs tasks of a public nature will not be an undertaking, and so will be immune from the application of the rules (cf. SAT Fluggesellschaft v Eurocontrol).

Economic entity principle

Generally art. 81(1) will only apply to the activities of two or more independent undertakings. The “economic entity doctrine makes clear that legally separate entities can be considered to be the same undertaking if they operate as a single entity on a market.” Cf. also Viho Europe BV v Commission.

In deciding whether an undertaking is truly autonomous from another, it is necessary to examine its different aspects of independence including its financial and managerial independence.

Agreements, decisions of associations and concerted practices

  • These terms are essentially interchangeable. In ACF Chemiefarma NV v Commission (“Quinine”) The court held that so-called gentleman’s agreement’s fell within art 81(1).

  • Whish suggests it is more of lingistuical distinction.

  • Rhone Poulenc SA v Commission (“Polypropylene”): …in order for there to be an agreement in the meaning of 81 it is sufficient that the undertakings in question should have expressed their joint intention to conduct themselves on the market in a specific way.”

  • An undertaking may be held responsible for a cartel even though it only participated in one of some of its constituent parts if it can be shown that it was aware of an overall plan to distort competition (Limburgse vinyl Maatschappj v Commision”.
  • Cf. also the Commission’s “Whistleblowing guidelines”.

Decisions by associations of undertakings

The difficulties faced by the Commission in proving a concerted practice makes it easier to establish the existence of a decision by an association of undertakings. Undertakings often participate through the auspices of either a trade or professional association set up to represent their interests. The actual form of the decision is not important; what is crucial is the potential limits placed on the freedom of action of an association’s members.

Concerted practices

  • The inclusion in art 81 of this term was designed to catch more informal means of cooperation.
  • Distinguishing parallel behaviour which genuine from that which not is not always an easy task, the essential difficulty  being one of proof. In “Dyestuffs” (ICI v Commission) the court expounded the famous definition of a concerted practice.

Although parallel behaviour may not by itself be identified with a concerted practice, it may however amount to strong evidence of such a practice if it leads to conditions of competition which do not correspond to the normal conditions of the market, having regard to the nature of the products, the size and number of the undertakings, and the volume of the said markets.

[more?]

Cf. also Suiker Unie and John Deere.

Oligopoly as a defence

The second issue to arise from the Court’s jurisprudence concerns behaviour which may in fact be a normal consequence of an oligopolistic market. There is clearly a very fine line between innocent parallel behaviour, which is acceptable and indeed commercially prudent, and the ‘knowing substitution of practical cooperation oft her risks of competition.

Ahlstorm Oy v Commission: [quarterly announcements of prices etc.] “… parallel conduct cannot be regarded a s furnishing proof on concertation unless concertation constitutes the only plausible explanation for such conduct.”

Unilateral conduct

  • Unilateral conduct can, in certain contexts, for example within a distribution system, amount to an agreement or concerted practices.
  • AEG-Telefunken v Commission
  • Selective distribution systems necessarily affect competition in the common market. Legitimate requirements, e.g. maintenance of a specialist trade capable of providing specific services as regards high-quality and high-technology products may justify a reduction of price competition in favour of competition relating to factors other than price.
  • Such systems are permissible, provided that resellers are chosen on the basis of objective criteria of a qualitative nature relating to the technical qualification s of the reseller, the suitability of trading premises and that such conditions are laid down uniformly for all potential resellers and are not applied in a discrimatory fashion (Cf. Metro v Commission).

  • Cf. also Ford (circular sent by the car manufacturer to its German dealers in which it suggested that it would not meet orders from them for right-hand-drive cars thus isolating markets in the UK and Ireland formed part of the contractual relations as an implied term) and Sandoz (set of continuous commercial relations of which the “export prohibited” clause formed an integral part, established by Sandoz and its customers was governed by a pre-established general agreement applicable to innumerable individual orders for Sandoz products).
  • Bayer v Commission:
  • As regards the form it is sufficient for a stipulation to be the expression of the parties’ intention to behave on the market in accordance with its terms without having to constitute a valid and binding contract under national law (“concurrence of wills”).
  • Measures adopted or imposed in an apparently unilateral manner by a manufacturer in the context of his continuing relations with his distributors have been regarded as constituting an agreement acc. to art. 81(1).

 The Commission’s reasoning had serious implications for the principle of freedom of contract.

Effect on trade between Member States

This part of the prohibition sets out the jurisdictional line between Community law and domestic competition law. The requirement has enjoyed a broad construction under art 81. The classic definition is enunciated in Societe Technique Miniere v Maschinenbau Ulm GmbH which sets out the extent of behaviour that is required to trigger Community competition law to apply.

  • STM: “To fulfil this condition, the agreement in question should, on the basis of a collection of objective legal or factual elements, allow one to expect, with a sufficient degree of probability, that it would exercise a direct or indirect, actual or potential, effect on the eddies of trade between Member-States.”

  • Consten and Grundig: The fact that an agreement encourages an increase, even a large one, in the volume of trade between states is not sufficient to exclude the possibility that the agreement may affect such trade.

  • An agreement between undertakings based in the same Member State may still have an effect on interstate trade (Windsurfing International Inc. v Commission and Delimitis [agreement between German brewer and German café proprietor]).

[See p. 193 on the increasing importance of “affect on interstate trade” in the context of the Commission’s Modernisation Regulation].

Appreciability and ‘de minimis’

If the effect is not “to an appreciable extent” the de minimis doctrine applies to limit the application of art 81. Where an agreement does not have an appreciable effect it will escape the prohibition in art 81 and there is no need to notify.

Join now!

Voelk v Vervaecke Sprl: “an agreement escapes the prohibition of art 81(1) where it has only an insignificant effect on the market, taking into account the weak position which the persons concerned have on the market of the product in question”.

The concept of appreciability is distinct from the requirement that the agreement should restrict competition.

Cf. De minimis Notice. The Notice introduces a market share threshold for networks of agreements producing a cumulative anticompetitive effect. It contains the same list of hard-core restrictions, which cannot benefit from the Notice as the Vertical and Horizontal Block Exemption ...

This is a preview of the whole essay