The Quest for Optimal Asset Allocation Strategies in Integrating Europe.

Authors Avatar

The Quest for the Optimal Asset Allocation Strategies in Integrating Europe        May 2004

Bachelor Thesis International Business Administration:

The Quest for Optimal Asset Allocation Strategies in Integrating Europe

Faarnaz Chavoushi

Erasmus University Rotterdam  

May 2004

Abstract:

This paper examines the effect of the process of monetary and economic integration in the EMU on the optimal diversification strategies for the mean-variance optimising investor. Previous literature has mostly focused on the relative importance of country versus sector effects for the explanation of stock returns, but following Ehling and Ramos (2002) and Moerman (2003), this paper takes a more practical approach to the question at hand. It aims to directly investigate the evolution of the optimal diversification strategy since the establishment of the EMU.  The methodology is based on the portfolio theory first introduced by Markowitz (1952), as well as the mean-variance spanning test initiated by Hubermann and Kandel (1987).

The paper finds that different diversification strategies have been optimal in the four different subsample periods specified, and that no clear trend is to be detected, except that diversification over both industries and countries has always been superior. These two findings cast doubt on the traditional top-down allocation strategy which is widely been used by most investment institutions, and which conventionally focuses on geographical diversification in the first place. Moreover, the results also indicate that recent argumentation for a shift in diversification strategy after the introduction of the Euro towards industry allocation is not entirely correct from an economical/statistical perspective.

OUTLINE OF CHAPTERS:

1. Introduction ……………………………………………………………………………….p.3

2. Research question.………………………………………………………………………..p. 5

3. Modern Portfolio Theory …………………………………………………………………p.6

4. International diversification benefits within the EMU

4.1 Correlations among European stock markets…………………………………...p.9

  1. Financial market integration in the EU………………………………………...p.13
  2. Country versus sector effects…………………………………………………..p.20
  3. Analysis of mean-variance frontiers…………………………………………...p.24

  1. Addition to the current body of knowledge……………………………………………p. 29

  1. Methodology

6.1 Methodology……………………………………………………………………p.30

6.2 Data………….………………………………………………………………….p.37

  1. Main empirical results
  1. Descriptive Statistics…………………………………………………………p.40
  2. Correlations………………………………………………………………...…p.42
  3. Efficient frontiers……………………………………………………………..P.49

  1. Main conclusions……………………………………………..………………………...p.53

9. References………………………………………………………………………………..p.57

        


1.         INTRODUCTION

The issue of European stock market integration is of considerable importance to both investors and the economy as a whole. Deregulation, elimination of cross-border restrictions on banking and securities transactions and the abolishment of currency risks, are all factors which have contributed to increased cross-border investment activity and accelerated equity capital flows between markets in the EMU. With exchange rates no longer a barrier to equity trading in the euro area, the European Commission is now working on harmonising and eliminating regulatory and structural obstacles such as cross-border trading restrictions, different accounting systems for financial reports and cross border trading costs. For that purpose, the Financial Services Action Plan has been established by the European Commission. The action plan is instituted so as to create an integrated European capital market that provides access to low cost capital and to foster a vibrant venture capital industry in Europe.

The gradual creation of a single market for equities is expected to raise competitiveness levels through the efficient allocation of capital, by mobilising savings to a larger and more liquid capital market, and by disciplining managers. In fact, the creation of an integrated European capital market is seen as one of the strategies set up to reach the goals of the Lisbon agenda and to outperform the American economy by 2010. However, although the elimination of currency exchange risk and the high degree of integration probably has substantial positive effects on the competitiveness of the European economy, its implications for the optimal asset allocation strategies of financial investment and security firms are somewhat ambiguous. In this paper, I would like to investigate the consequences of the ongoing European integration for investors in Europe in terms of stock market diversification.

Optimal stock market diversification strategy for EU investors has been a topic of much debate in the recent years. Until a few years ago, it was common practice among portfolio managers to follow a top-down approach to asset selection. The first step of the top-down approach involved deciding on a country allocation grid, effectively placing first priority on an adequate geographical diversification of portfolios. The second step entailed selecting the best securities in accord with this allocation, that is, within each national market to the extent permitted by the grid. The top-down approach was supported by the standard perception that spreading the portfolio among different countries provided the optimal diversification results.  However, at the end of the 1990s, the argument was increasingly made that the country orientation of the top-down approach should give way, within the euro-era at least, to an industry or sector orientation. This proposal is based on the observation that as stocks become more integrated and move increasingly together, the diversification benefits of investing in many countries may well be reduced. Therefore, the focus of diversification should shift from a country level to the industry level across European markets. As a result, superannuation funds and life insurance companies that hold long-term investment portfolios and adopt policies of passive international diversification, are increasingly expected to switch portfolio compositions in order to achieve efficient portfolios. This change in asset allocation strategy is not a minor change, since it implies that the teams of analysts now organised among country lines, are to be reorganised along industry lines. Many investment firms are in the process of following this advice, which implies that they will put less time and effort into examining the macroeconomic outlook of a country, instead predominantly focusing on analysing the prospects of an industry and of specific firms within that industry. In this thesis, I would like to examine whether this recent shift of asset allocation strategy is justified, both from a theoretical and empirical perspective.

The paper will first start by formulating the research questions and objectives of this study. Then it will explain the rationale of international diversification strategies by discussing the mean-variance optimisation theory of Markowitz. It will then continue to review those theories and literature related to the topic of international diversification benefits within the EMU, including: factors affecting cross-country correlations, the question of financial integration within the EMU, and the importance of country versus industry effects in explaining equity returns. After this theoretical review, the methodology and data set employed for the empirical research are described. The basic statistics of the sample data are discussed afterwards, followed by the main empirical results concerning the stability of correlations, and an examination of diversification benefits of each investment opportunity in a mean-variance allocating framework. Finally, the empirical results are put into perspective by comparing the findings of this study with other literature.  

2.        RESEARCH QUESTION:

The establishment of the European Monetary System and the establishment of the European Monetary Union in 1979 brought many institutional changes that had substantial converging effects on the real economy of the member countries, and have thereby possibly also led to an increase in the integration of financial markets in the EMU.  An increase in financial integration suggests higher correlations among stock returns between different country indices, which jeopardises international diversification benefits as suggested by the mean-variance portfolio model first introduced by Markowitz.

Many authors have therefore suggested that stock diversification strategies should concentrate more on the industrial composition of the portfolio. Accordingly, institutional investors in practice have started to change the structure of the traditional top-down approach to asset selection. In the past, this approach concentrated on first dividing the money over several countries and secondly how to spread the investment within a country. The new one-step strategy advocated recently, primarily focuses on diversification among industries rather than geographical diversification in the first place.

I would like to investigate whether this new structure of top-down asset allocation according to industry correlations is the optimal strategy for an investor with a mean-variance perspective.

The research question of this paper therefore is:

What are the implications of the process of economic and monetary integration in the EMU for the optimal diversification strategy of a mean-variance optimising investor in Europe?

In order to address this broad research question, I will try to answer the following sub questions:

  • Is it possible to construct a more efficient portfolio by diversifying over EU industry sectors, rather than diversifying over the country indices of the EMU member states?
  • Does the addition of sector indices to country indices significantly shift the efficient mean-variance frontier of a pure country or industry diversification strategy?
  • Has the optimal diversification strategy changed over time as the integration of the European financial markets has progressed?
  • Is the recent shift in asset allocation strategy observed in practice justified from an academic perspective?

3.         MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY:

Financial economists typically model investment as a problem of constrained optimisation under uncertainty. The expected utility framework shows the theoretical relationship between the elements of this problem: the portfolio possibilities set, the probability distribution of asset returns (describing the investor’s subjective expectations about the future), and the investor’s utility function (describing the investor’s investment objectives). However, since we do not know the precise shape of the expected utility framework, or the probability distribution of returns, the mean-variance framework is a popular approximation to the expected utility framework. It is widely used for applications of portfolio selection, performance evaluation and risk management. Amongst other things, it helps investors to select optimally diversified (or mean-variance efficient) portfolios. Linking the mean-variance analysis to the general expected utility framework is justified when the return distribution can be approximated by a normal distribution or when the utility function can be approximated by a quadratic function. In most cases, at least the latter condition is satisfied and hence the mean-variance analysis gives a good approximation to the general expected utility framework.

Markowitz, the founder of modern portfolio theory, first introduced the theory of mean-variance optimisation and diversification benefits in 1952. He showed that a portfolio must satisfy one of these two criteria in order to maximise the investor’s expected utility:

For a given level of return, it must offer the lowest risk, or

for a given level of risk, it must offer the highest level of return.

Since investors are assumed to prefer a high return and a lower risk, expected utility is assumed to be an increasing function of the mean, and a decreasing function of the variance.

Using the mean-variance criterion, investors will focus on the set of portfolios with the smallest variance for a given mean; the mean-variance frontier (see Figure 4 below). An investment that is not dominated by any other investment is called mean-variance efficient. An efficient portfolio is a portfolio that has the highest possible expected return for a given standard deviation. The mean-variance portfolio is the portfolio that provides the lowest variance (standard deviation) among all possible portfolios of risky assets. The segment above point MPV is called the efficient frontier, and it includes all of the efficient portfolios. When a risk free asset is available, then there is one Capital Asset Line with the highest reward to variability ratio (so-called Sharpe ratio; (expected return – risk free rate) / standard deviation) that connects to one of the risky portfolios. The CAL which yields the highest possible slope from the risk free asset (and thus provides the largest expected return per unit of risk), is tangent to one portfolio of risky assets on the efficient frontier; the so-called the tangency portfolio. The tangency portfolio is therefore the portfolio that maximises the reward to variability ratio. Investors choose the appropriate mix between the tangency portfolio and the risk free asset, based on his or her own risk aversion.

Fig 1. Illustration of a mean-variance frontier:

The mean-variance efficiency criterion allows only for a partial ordering of the choice alternatives, and therefore does not yield a ranking for all investment options; nor does it forward the ‘best’ or the ‘worst’ option.

Markowitz (1952, 1959) showed that an investment in a portfolio of securities offers investors risk and return combinations that are not possible from individual securities. In order to do so, he quantified the difference between the risk of portfolio assets taken individually and the overall risk of the portfolio. He showed that the variance (and thus the risk) of a portfolio is determined by the variances of the underlying assets, the covariances or the correlations and the choice of weights:

 

where is the variance of the portfolio,  and  are the variances of the individual assets,  is the correlation between asset 1 and asset 2, and the w’s are the weights of the individual assets in the portfolio. The formula shows that the risk of a portfolio is not equal to the sum of the weighted average of the variances of the individual securities, but also depends on the correlation of the two.

Therefore, the weaker the correlations between assets are, the greater is the reduction in portfolio risk. Hence, a ‘risky’ asset (that is, an asset with a high variance) can actually lower the portfolio variance if it has a low covariance with the assets that have a high weight in the portfolio.  As a consequence, for the same level of risk, the performance of a diversified portfolio is better than that of a portfolio that is less diversified. It is should therefore be the aim of the investor to diversify his investments by selecting those investment assets that have a low level of correlation with each other.

Diversification can be done across asset classes (stocks, bonds, commodities), across sectors and industries, or across regions and countries. Portfolio diversification eliminates the influence of what is called idiosyncratic risk – the unpredictable fluctuations specific to individual security returns. Diversification among asset classes or industries within a single country however, leaves exposure to ‘systematic’ risk, the unpredictable losses that affect all domestic securities (this systematic risk is often assumed to be reflected by the variability of excess returns in a market-value weighted index portfolio). Systematic risk comes from the common exposure of assets to economy-wide risk factors, such as the business cycle, interest rates and exchange rates. Because domestic systematic risks are likely to differ from country to country, international diversification can further reduce the volatility of portfolio returns by mitigating country specific risk. More internationally diversified portfolios should as a consequence shift the frontier of efficient portfolios upwards and therefore for each given risk the average portfolio return should increase. However, as correlations among country returns increase, the case for international diversification weakens.


4.        INTERNATIONAL DIVERSFICIATION WITHIN THE EMU:

4.1                 Correlations among European stock markets:

The simplest way of evaluating the attractiveness of diversification strategies in the EU market is to calculate and analyse the correlations of country and industry indices. After all, as we have seen, the rationale of international diversification highly depends on low correlations between international equity markets. There are a number of reasons why traditionally, low correlations are expected across developed equity markets:

Country specific shocks

Important economic shocks such as fiscal (relating to the budget deficit of a country) or monetary policy (movements in interest rates) specific to a country, affect firms differently across countries. Other domestic economic shocks and differences are for example the differences in productivity indices, labour legislation, and national growth rates. Alternatively it may be that national markets respond differently to global shocks, because differences in institutions across countries affect the transmission of global shocks to asset values. Either way, economic shocks can cause variation in stock returns that is country specific.

Home bias in the portfolio holdings of investors.

Instead of diversifying across all markets and holding a portfolio that mirrors the world portfolio, investors have historically strongly overweighed domestic securities in their portfolios (French and Poterba (1991), Cooper and Kaplanis (1994), Tesar and Werner (1995) and Warnoch (2001)). What the home equity bias puzzle implies is that the elimination of formal barriers to capital flows, such as capital controls and transaction costs, has not been sufficient to induce cross-border capital flows as predicted by various asset pricing models. Accounting for factors such as risk aversion and uncertainties,  exchange rate risk, has been shown to explain some part of the equity home bias, although the puzzle remains largely unsolved (Lewis 1999). If the marginal investor of Dutch securities lives in Holland, and the marginal investor in French securities in France and they evaluate stocks relative to other stocks in their country, country portfolios may in part reflect the different sentiment of Dutch and French investors.  

Segmentation of financial markets

When home bias dominates and national markets are segmented, the prices and returns of the corresponding securities are disconnected. The demand and supply of savings are matched country by country and the risk aversion depends largely on local circumstances. Since

pricing differences are not arbitraged away – there is no way to trade on the basis of relative capital abundance and relative willingness to take risk -, local capital market conditions determine the equity return on the national markets (Adjaoute et al, 2003). The segmentation of financial markets thus results in a difference of the price of risk across countries.

Segmentation can be triggered by for example by the home bias effect, informational barriers,  transactions barriers and costs of trade, so that consequently, the market price of systematic risk factors differs across markets. Segmentation may also be caused by various restrictions which limit ownership of foreign assets, such as currency matching rules or general restrictions with respect to weights placed on foreign assets affecting pension funds and life insurance companies.

Many different researchers have investigated the evolution of correlations among sector and country portfolios over time. There is substantial empirical evidence that correlations are time varying and that correlations across markets increase during periods of higher economic and financial integration. The tests of Goetzmann et al (2001) also suggest that the structure of global correlations shifts considerably through time. Time-series of average correlations are actually found to show a ‘U’ shaped pattern, with the global economic and financial integration achieving comparable levels around the beginning of the 20th Century to what we have today (also noted by Obstfeld and Taylor (2001)).  Similarly, Longin and Solnik (1995) study the shifts in global correlations from the 1960s to 1990. This analysis leads to the rejection of the hypothesis of a constant conditional correlation structure. Their more recent study (2001), focusing on the correlation during extreme months, finds evidence of positive international equity market correlation shifts conditional upon market drops over the past 38 years. This implies that when diversification benefits are needed most (in times of market decline),  they are most hard to find due to higher correlations

Goetzmann, Li and Rouwenhorst (2001) conclude that periods of free capital flows are associated with high correlations. Various authors support these presumptions with empirical research. For example, looking at the EMU correlations, Rouwenhorst (1999) finds that both country and sector correlations are increasing over time in the period of 1978-1998,  although the average increase is not as pronounced for sectors as it is for countries.

Various researchers have concluded that the international diversification potential today is very low compared to the rest of capital market history. Goetzmann, Li and Rouwenhorst (2001) for example collect information from 150 years of global equity market history in order to evaluate the evolution of equity correlation matrices through time. They find that today, in the beginning of the 21st Century, global correlations are at a historical high – approaching levels of correlation last experienced during the Great Depression.  

Surprisingly, however, more recent empirical research from other authors who examined the correlation structure of European stock markets, are not in line with this earlier conclusion.

For example, in an early paper, Adjaoute and Danthine (2000) first identified a significant increase in the degree of correlation between national stock indices implying  diversification opportunities had been significantly reduced after the introduction of the euro. However after revisiting their earlier work in mid 2001 with a extended sample data, they find that more recent data convey a radically different message. They find that the period after the introduction of the euro is characterised by lower correlations than those obtained for the immediately preceding period of the same length. Another example of a recent study which reports a trend in the cross-country return correlation within the EMU, is the paper by Ferreira (2003). Examining the period 1975 till 2001, they find that both EMU country and industry correlations reach a peak in the 1995-1998 period, and then decrease in the last period.

These findings are surprising, since the introduction of the euro is said to have eased the transfer of capital within the European Union, and based on the analysis of Goetzmann et al, one would expect higher correlations in such periods. However, although these recent studies undermine the earlier conclusion of Goetzmann et al on the relationship between free capital flows and high correlations, they  offer support for another conclusion by Goetzmann et al considering the time varying pattern of correlation matrices. In particular, Adjaoute et al identify interesting low frequency movements in dispersions suggestive of cycles and long swings in return correlations.  

Research shows that industry correlations have historically been higher than country correlations. For example Ferreira (2003) reports a correlation average of 0.358 for countries and 0.574 for industries for the whole sample period of 1975-2001.

However, recent studies suggest that differences between average country and average industry correlations are narrowing. As mentioned above, Rouwenhorst (1999) for example found that the average increase in correlations for countries is higher than for industries. And from the results of Ferreira (2003), it can be conducted that the ratio of industry correlations to country correlations was 3.15 in the period 1975-1978, but that during the period of 1999-2001, average industry correlations were only 1.11 times higher than country correlations. These studies suggest that we may be near an inflection point, or at least a levelling between the two factors.


4.2                 Financial market integration in the EU:

The topic of time-varying correlation levels is often associated with different levels of monetary and financial integration over time. In this chapter, the issue of financial integration within Europe will be examined. The chapter will first describe a number of developments in the real sector that would strongly suggest the occurrence of financial integration in the EMU. Afterwards, a short review of the literature on this topic will be presented. Finally, a conceptual outline will be given on the link between the issue of monetary and financial integration and cross-country correlations.  

In the literature, national stock markets are defined to be completely integrated if investors face only common EU-wide risk factors and price them identically. Markets are said to be partially integrated if, in addition to common-EU wide factors, investors face country specific factors and price them both. As financial integration proceeds, higher risk country specific factors should become less important in the pricing of investments and lower risk, EU wide, factors become more important. As a consequence, risk sharing among member countries should increase leading to an overall reduction in the cost of equity capital.

Join now!

The decrease in equity premium is reasoned by Stulz (1999) and further explained in the paper by Adjaoute et al (2003). They argue that under segmentation, the appropriate measure of risk for a local country portfolio is its standard deviation. When the price per unit of risk is denoted by P, the risk premium on a given security i in the segmented market is therefore , where is the variance of the returns on asset i. In a completely integrated financial market however, investors hold internationally diversified portfolios. The proper measure of risk for the local country portfolio is then ...

This is a preview of the whole essay