"The serious problem is the education of the peasantry. The peasant economy is scattered, and the socialization of agriculture, judging by the Soviet Union's experience, will require a long time and painstaking work.

Authors Avatar

Jaede Tan            China project – Developing Economies                     March 2003                                                                              

“The serious problem is the education of the peasantry. The peasant economy is scattered, and the socialization of agriculture, judging by the Soviet Union’s experience, will require a long time and painstaking work. Without socialization of agriculture, there can be no complete, consolidated socialism”

Chairman Mao Ze Dong

“On the People’s Democratic Dictatorship” June 30, 1949, Selected Works, Vol. IV, p.419

By the 1990’s to what extent had government reform policies of the 1980’s in China, been successful in integrating China’s rural sector into the new industrial economy?

By Jaede Tan

Previous studies on the historic trend of inequality in China throughout the development periods (pre-Maoist era, Maoist era and the reform period) have on the whole been in agreement that there was, pre-Mao, a period of relatively high inequality in China, a decline in inequality during the Maoist era, and then a rise in inequality in the post-Mao reform period. If we, therefore, plot the level of inequality against time, such authors as Bramall, Khan and Rozelle agree on a “U-shaped” graph, with the trough representing the relatively low inequality experienced during the Maoist era. Where previous studies have disagreed is to the degree of decline of inequality in the Maoist period. Rozelle argues for a sharp decline in inequality in this time period, and hence a steep drop in the aforementioned “U-shaped” graph, whereas Bramall argues a much shallower “U”. In any case these studies are in agreement as to the general trend of inequality in China. The reform period did cause a rise in disparity in China in comparison to the levels enjoyed in the Maoist era.

I will, in my study, examine the trend in inequality in rural and urban areas, before going on to examine rural-urban inequality levels and then interregional inequality between “coastal”, “interior” and “western” provinces. I will be using consolidated data sets from previous studies and tailoring them to be used for my own purposes.

It should be noted that the accuracy of data sets for China over this time period is difficult to gauge for a variety of reasons. The absence of a banking sector and accounting records especially in rural areas, makes it very difficult to measure exact income and consumption levels. As a result of this, income and consumption figures were often obtained by means of survey, which along with being imprecise may also have been biased towards reporting favourable data by the Chinese government. Local government leaders would have been against reporting poor economic figures for their respective areas and so may have “cooked the books” or biased their surveys in order to report favourable data. Such a mentality was seen in the agricultural communes under Mao where harvest results were vastly exaggerated to please higher authorities. Another problem with gathering data in China is the sheer scale of the country both in landmass and in population. For the time period I am studying, the population was roughly 600 million, one quarter of the total world population at the time. It is, therefore, easy to see how collecting data for such a large sample size is extremely difficult.  

Under Mao there was a high drive towards rapidly expanding the economy and increasing output. This was done by setting high regional goals, an ideology of self-sufficiency and by channelling all resources to agriculture. As a result other industries suffered. The government also provided regional objectives through redistribution policies. These included subsidizing social programs in poor areas, interregional transfers of investment resources and an organisation to provide relief in times of famine and/or disaster. According to Rozelle these changes led to income inequality falling from a Gini coefficient of between 0.35 to 0.39, for a set of villages in Hebei province, pre-Mao, to a level of 0.22 during the Maoist era.

During the reform period, policies were aimed at promoting the necessary level of growth by decollectivizing agriculture and by diversifying the economy out of agriculture especially in rural areas. Between the late 1978 and the mid-1980’s government reform policies were focused primarily on increasing agricultural output, but in the late 1980’s the focus was shifted towards increasing industry. The idea of self-sufficiency was removed and local markets were encouraged. On a growth side, the results of this were extremely encouraging. Grain and rural incomes increased rapidly in most provinces in the early 1980s, and rural output grew at more than 20% between 1984 and 1988. From 1978 to 1993 China's per capita GNP increased in real terms by around 280 percent, even though inflation was high in the late 1980’s. The problem that arose was the rising inequality that previous research agrees arose as a result of the new structure of the reform economy.

The rural economy:

Mao saw and recognised the need to boost the economy primarily through the agricultural sector. To achieve this he established a collective system of agriculture that later developed into a communal system, promoting equality and self-sufficiency. It would therefore follow that equality in rural areas was an important by-product of Maoist policy. In fact, the equality of the peasant mass was enforced by the government through a strict rationing of items such as food and clothing to each commune member. Rations were distributed to each peasant according to need, and so there was no personal incentive to individually produce more. However in the reform period, agriculture was decollectivized and markets were established that encouraged entrepreneurship and increased personal incentives to increase output. This would imply an increase in disparity.  

Join now!

Table 1: Gini Coefficients of Rural Households in China, 1979-1988

Chai also collected Gini coefficients for the above data, and although his results are not exactly identical to those of Rozelle, the trend that shown is alike. As Gini coefficients deal with income inequality, the data shows that there is a definite rise in income disparity as a result of the reform of agriculture in the countryside. The removal of the strict communal allocation of resources to each peasant individually gave way to markets and profit incentives, encouraging private enterprise. As a direct result of this, ...

This is a preview of the whole essay