Implications for the macro-economy of the central bank adopting an interest rate rule. John Taylor, a Stanford economist, was able to devise a simple rule for Federal Reserve actions which has received considerable acclaim for its accuracy in capturing t

Authors Avatar

Running Head: IMPLICATIONS FOR THE MACRO-ECONOMY OF THE CENTRAL BANK ADOPTING AN INTEREST RATE RULE

Implications for the macro-economy of the central bank adopting an interest rate rule

(Name of the writer)

(Name of the institution)

ABSTRACT

John Taylor devised a simple monetary policy rule that links the Federal Reserve's policy interest rate with inflation and output targets. This paper compares actual policy rates with the rates that would have been recommended by the basic Taylor Rule for three long periods in U.S. economic history: 1875-1913 ("Pre Fed"), 1914-1951 ("Early Fed"), and 1952-1998 ("Modern Fed"). In addition, the authors develop a more complex version of the Rule to facilitate a comparison of the way in which each monetary authority would have reacted to the economic challenges presented outside its own time period. The empirical evidence suggests that Modern Fed would have reacted more promptly and appropriately to inflation and output problems outside its time period than either Early Fed or Pre Fed, and that the movement of interest rates in the Pre Fed period came closer to the corrective policies of Modern Fed than did those of Early Fed.  

Table of Contents

Chapter I        

1. Introduction        

Chapter II        

2. The Taylor Rule And Its Historical Application        

Chapter III        

3. The Enhanced Model        

Chapter IV        

4. Empirical Results And Inter-period Comparison        

Chapter V        

5. Conclusion        

Chapter I

1. Introduction

For the most part, the Federal Reserve has exercised its monetary policy actions over the decades on the basis of discretion rather than policy rules. The complexity of the process involving multiple monetary policy instruments working through multiple intermediate targets to hit multiple policy goals would seem to favor a discretionary, rather than rules, approach. Yet John Taylor, a Stanford economist, was able to devise a simple rule for Federal Reserve actions which has received considerable acclaim for its accuracy in capturing the essence of the monetary process.

As Taylor pointed out, a number of macroeconomic policy actions are predicated upon rules, not discretion. Fiscal policy, for example, is often divided into two parts: discretionary policy actions and automatic "stabilizers" to the economy such as progressive income taxes which automatically reduce consumer spending and slow the economy during periods of excessive inflation, and unemployment benefits, which increase consumer spending and stimulate the economy during periods of high unemployment. Fixed exchange rate policies tend to serve as a rule requiring governments to "lean against" the market winds that serve to push currency exchange rates higher or lower than the established target. International economic policy discussions are frequently oriented toward the study of the merits of flexible vs. fixed exchange rates, the international equivalent of the discretion vs. rules controversy.

In the pre-Federal Reserve era, the gold standard served as a monetary policy rule, permitting the money supply to rise only with the emergence of new sources of gold. A rule of sorts was followed by the Federal Reserve when it was required by the Treasury to purchase the large volume of Treasury bonds that kept interest rates artificially low during WWII and the early post-war years. For a short time (1979-82) the Federal Reserve attempted to follow a variation of the constant growth rate of money rule advocated by Milton Friedman.

Generally, however, the Federal Reserve has shown a decided preference for unfettered discretion in conducting monetary policy. The movement towards an inflation-only goal by some central banks, and the development in 1993 by Professor Taylor of a monetary policy rule linking inflation and output targets have stimulated fresh interest in the discretion vs. rules debate.

One of the beneficial by-products of Taylor's Rule is its capacity to compare the actual behavior of the monetary authority in terms of the setting of short-term interest rates with what that behavior should have been in the context of implied inflation and output goals. Specifically, given the assumptions underlying the Rule, one could judge not only whether the Fed moved the short-term rate in the appropriate direction, but also whether it captured the magnitude of the policy change correctly.

This paper incorporates the judgmental element of the Rule to examine the conduct of monetary policy over three long periods in U.S. economic history: 1875-1913 ("Pre Fed"); 1914-1951 ("Early Fed"); and 1952-1998 ("Modem Fed"). We go beyond the issue of which monetary authority was most effective in dealing with the inflation (or deflation) and output challenges of its time to obtain a glimpse of how each would have handled the economic situations encountered by the other. For example, how would the Modern Fed have reacted in response to the economic conditions of the Great Depression? Would the actions theoretically taken by the Early Fed during the prolonged period of deflation in the late 1800s have been an improvement over those of Pre Fed period?

Although the answers to such questions can never be known with certainty, this paper attempts to provide some insights through employment of both simple and sophisticated versions of the Taylor Rule over the past 125 years. It should be clearly acknowledged that at times over such a long span goals other than inflation and output have correctly enjoyed higher priorities. Also, it would be impossible to ascertain precisely how any macro economy would react to different policy actions than those taken. Nonetheless, the inferences drawn from historical inspection shed some light on the progress (or lack thereof) of the U.S. monetary authority in moving along an extended learning curve.  

Chapter II

2. The Taylor Rule And Its Historical Application

Taylor's Rule (1993) specified that the nominal federal funds rate should be set by the Federal Reserve as a function of the inflation rate and the GDP gap. Taylor (1998) developed these core relationships in the linear equation:

r = π + gy + h ( π - π * ) + r f (1)

where r = the short-term nominal interest rate, π = the inflation rate (percentage change in the price level), y = the GDP gap = 100 ln(real GDP / trend real GDP) and g, h, Π*, and r f = are constants. Specifically, π* = target inflation rate, r f = equilibrium real rate of interest, h = amount by which the central authority raises the ex post real interest rate (r - π) in response to an increase in inflation and g = amount by which the central authority raises the real interest rate in response to a rise in real output above its trend (or potential).

Employing quarterly data for the period 1984.1 - 1992.3, Taylor (1993) selected, as appropriate for the time, an inflation target of 2 percent and a 2 percent equilibrium real interest rate (observed to be close to the 2.2 percent real GDP trend for the period). He also selected weights of g = 0.5 and h = 0.5, although in the later (1998) paper, he observed that recent research suggests setting g, the real output weight, at 1.0. Note that if both inflation and real GDP are precisely on target, y = 0, (π - Π*) = 0, π = 2, r f = 2, then r, the nominal policy interest rate is set equal to 4 percent and the equilibrium real interest rate is 2 percent.

Join now!

An important feature of the Rule is that simple application of these selected parameters to the 1984-92 period proved surprisingly successful in replicating the actual movement of the Fed's primary policy instrument, the nominal federal funds interest rate. By implication, the Federal Reserve was reacting to the economic environment as described by Taylor's Rule, or something like it, in establishing monetary policy. This feature of Taylor's approach contributed in no small measure to its immediate popularization in both research and policy studies.

The Taylor Rule's basic approach to policy inference can be applied to a more extended period of U.S. ...

This is a preview of the whole essay