Have government interventions in the economies of independent Southeast Asian countries been a force for stability or instability?

Authors Avatar

“Have government interventions in the economies of independent Southeast Asian countries been a force for stability or instability?”

Government intervention in the economies of Southeast Asian countries became necessary after independence as early as 1945, due to the historical context that they faced, and formed an intimate relationship between politics and the economy, both directly and indirectly.

Economic stability depends not only on the meeting of certain economic requirements, but also on the prior development of certain social and political frameworks, chiefly a strong and stable government, an honest, efficient, and technically trained bureaucracy, imaginative entrepreneurial talent with freedom to operate and a cohesive social community. Hence, it can be said that only by meeting the preceding terms, government intervention can contribute towards shaping a stable economy - having low inflation and uninterrupted economic growth - and achieving social stability, through the diminution of rural discontent and unrest. Yet, it is also imperative to note that an unstable economy can still experience gradual growth and should not be critiqued too hastily.

Speak about the economies of post-war SEA, and corruption and cronyism, as a result of governments inducting them into the economy, would immediately come to mind. It was by large the biggest factor that caused economies that were both prospering and declining to wane further. However, cronyism was also a force for social and economic stability, in that the lack of social capital led to the absence of horizontal interest groups, thus insulating economic policies from parochial pressure on the conduct of economic management. This proliferation of cronyism also developed a constructive social structure, in which the mutual reliance of the patron-client relationships led to satisfaction in the part of both the government and the involved companies, thus resulting in social stability. Hence, cronyism could conceivably be regarded as the price that had to be paid for stability.

Another case in point would be Malaysia, where political and economical favours were reciprocated by financial and electoral support for government officials. Government leaders exploited the New Economic Policy (NEP) to award contracts to UMNO-linked enterprises, creating a large, influential group of indigenous ethnic groups that in fact simply augments UMNO political dominance. This in turn ensures social stability through mutual subsistence. Furthermore, the Chinese in Malaysia, who were victimised, were able to forge alliances with UMNO leaders to stay ahead in the economy and exploit their expertise to facilitate economic growth and hence stability.

Join now!

A better case to illustrate this would be Indonesia. Suharto disbursed concessions to his cronies as a means of consolidating his political control and economic reforms were instigated in the interests of domestic capitalists. This relationship removed other powerful horizontal interest groups, and hence Suharto and his economists were able to revive the once-devastated economy of Sukarno. Newly introduced corporatist structures served effectively to contain the industry politically, minimizing the scope for collective action. Consequently the monetary authorities engineered a steady depreciation of the currency while avoiding excessive inflation, and hence maintained an average surplus of 0.7% in the ...

This is a preview of the whole essay