Organizational Theory: So Far, So Good… So What?

Authors Avatar

        

Organizational Theory: So Far, So Good… So What?

Organizational theory has moved a great distance from the beginning of the 20th century; it has an even greater distance to go.  The narrative of the development of organization theory begins with scientific management (Taylor 1911), continues through classical bureaucratic studies (Weber and Gerth 1958) and so-called “natural” approaches (Barnard 1938), but then splits into two very different open-systems categories.  One is a rational, economic/political branch, which starts with bounded rationality (March and Simon 1958), moves through contingency theory (Lawrence and Lorsch 1967), then (much) later blooms into the “new economics of organization,” based on theories that seek to explain the existence and structure of organizations as solutions to cooperation or coordination problems; here the exemplar is transaction cost (Williamson 1985) economics.  The other is a natural, sociological/psychological branch, which includes garbage can theory (March and Olsen 1986), population ecology (Hannan and Freeman 1977), and the new (sociological) insitutionalism (Meyer and Rowan 1977). How do these approaches differ in terms of levels-of-analysis covered, explanatory power, and potential for future growth?  Following these two historical paths, two trends are clear: the sophistication and combination of different levels of analysis continually improves, and with each additional theoretical model, further puzzles are solved.  However, with the deep chasm separating the sociological/psychological and economic/political branches, future prospects look bleak for these groups to engage in the type of constructive dialogue that could lead to further innovations.

The first few organizational scholars used relatively simple conceptual models to explain organizational behavior, restricting their analyses to a single level of analysis and a few assumptions.  Taylor focused on workers on the shop floor (individual level of analysis).  While most of his work concerned prescriptions to improve productivity rather than grand theorizing, to do so he introduced the concept of the rational worker, who performed his duties in a sub-optimal fashion.  His solution involved eliminating as much discretion as possible from the workers in order to force them to work in a more productive manner (and, in some cases, paying them more).  Consequently, from Taylor’s model, we can explain why workers slack off: it is in their interest to do so.

Like Taylor, Weber was interested in prescriptions for organizing. However, he was much more interested in the structure of the organization than he was in the actions of individuals, and thus moved organizational theory up to a more abstract level of analysis.  He constructed a model of bureaucratic (as opposed to traditional or charismatic) organizations: authority was based on the office, not on the individual; technical competence was prized; the division of labor was fixed.  The benefit of this form of organization was that it was more stable, predictable, and reliable than other forms.  This conceptualization explains why bureaucracies have proliferated: they were a superior form of organization.

Join now!

However, Weber left out the flipside of the formal bureaucratic structure. Charles Barnard’s innovation in organizational theory was to emphasize the importance of the informal structure of organizations.  He focused on cooperation problems, and concluded that a better solution to Taylor’s slacking problem was to get workers to internalize the goals of the organization through socialization.  In doing so, he operated at both the individual and organizational level at once: individuals were assumed to be susceptible to social coercion; the key to coercion is the structure of the organization. Thus he provided a dual-level, normative explanation as to why some ...

This is a preview of the whole essay