Outline the effects of the communist party on Chinese national development

Authors Avatar

Outline the effects of the communist party on Chinese national development

The People's Republic of China came into being on October the first 1949. Since that time the leadership of the Communist Party of China (CPC), the country's ruling party, has attempted to bring about social reconstruction and economic growth by employing different variants of 'socialist' policy. A number of periods may be identified, each characterised by particular policy directions and emphases. The principal aspects and implications of each of these will be discussed, beginning with the Rehabilitation period of 1949-52.

In 1949 the Chinese communists inherited a country which was backward, poor and underdeveloped due to continuing Imperial patterns of class structure, as well as having been ravaged by two civil wars and a Japanese invasion since the 1920s (Cannon and Jenkins 1990). Before the communist development envisaged by Mao Zedong's revolutionary government could begin, it was necessary to establish administrative control over the entire territory, as well as to revive the devastated economy. The former was effectively achieved by a four tier hierarchical spatial structure with six regions as the largest divisions and thousands of 'administrative villages', each consisting of a number of natural villages as the smallest (Riskin 1987). Economic rehabilitation was partly facilitated by deflationary policies, including central control of the new currency, the renminbi (RMB or yuan), which brought inflation under control by early 1950 (ibid). The encouragement of production, however, was also a necessary part of this revival, and one which had to be achieved alongside the socialist transformation of the relations of production required by the CPC's ideological beliefs. In the rural areas this compromise was effected by land reform policies which, while eliminating the landlord class and improving the lot of poor peasants, "deliberately stopped short of complete economic equality" (Riskin 1987, 50) in order to maintain the productive capacity of rich peasants. In urban industry economic strategy was aimed, at least initially, at encouraging the productive potential of 'national capitalists' although directing this potential towards the fulfilment of the state's objectives, while monopoly capital was centralised. By 1952, 56% of gross industrial output value (GIOV) and 63.7% of trade volume was controlled by the state (Lippit 1987).

`The land reform, while stopping short of complete redistribution and, it must be noted, bought at the cost of the lives of perhaps four million landlords, benefitted 60-70% of all peasants (ibid). In general economic terms, the first three years of communist rule in China saw agriculture and industry restored to levels of performance equal to or greater than past peak levels, although absolute production remained very low, with per capita grain output as well as that of coal steel and electric power all below half the level of those present in the Soviet Union immediately prior to its First Five Year Plan in 1952 (Riskin 1987). Nevertheless, it was on this foundation that the development of China was to be attempted.

The First Five Year Plan (FFYP), inaugurated in 1953, was based around the development of large-scale industry, particularly heavy producer goods industries such as iron and steel production, along Soviet lines and with Soviet aid, both financial and technological. In the interests of geographical allocative fairness, over 55% of this investment was to occur in inland regions, away from the traditional industrial centres of the East coast such as Shanghai (ibid). State control of the large majority of industrial and commercial operations was a central component of the overall industrial development policy, as well as a goal in itself due to fears within the CPC over the threat to the new regime posed by internal counter-revolutionaries in private capitalist industry, and exacerbated by the nearby presence of the Americans during the Korean war (ibid). As well as providing for military security, industrial growth was seen as instrumental in enabling the increases in agricultural technology fundamental to increased living standards. That there was no explicit concentration on agricultural technology in the FFYP is indicative of the CPC leadership's belief by 1954 that agricultural growth was to be achieved by effective socialist organisation, and that the rapid industrial development enabled by this growth could then improve agricultural technology (ibid). The encouragement of farm and handiwork co-operatives with a view to eventual collectivisation, therefore, was a significant component of the FFYP. The gradual path to large-scale socialist agricultural institutions was to be facilitated in this period by the progressive establishment of increasingly large and organisationally centralised collectives (see for instance Lippit 1987).

Join now!

`The immediate effects of the FFYP were generally beneficial. While the massive industrialisation program gave rise to high unemployment levels, largely due to the widening gap between rural and urban incomes, it also succeeded in achieving remarkably high growth rates, particularly those of well over 20% in heavy industry (Hsueh and Woo 1991), and did not lead directly to any actual drop in living standards (Riskin 1987). Larger agricultural collectives had advantages over earlier farming systems in terms of organisation and efficiency, as well as benefitting poorer peasants by more egalitarian distribution of overall benefits.

`The transitional nature of such ...

This is a preview of the whole essay